8. The Laws of Motion of the
Capitalist Mode of Production
If Marx's theory of
surplus-value is his most revolutionary contribution to economic
science, his discovery of the basic long-term ‘laws of
motion’ (development trends) of the capitalist mode of
production constitutes undoubtedly his most impressive
scientific achievement. No other 19th-century author has been
able to foresee in such a coherent way how capitalism would
function, would develop and would transform the world, as did
Karl Marx. Many of the most distinguished contemporary
economists, starting with Wassily Leontief (1938), and Joseph
Schumpeter (1942) have recognised this.
While some of these ‘laws of
motion’ have obviously created much controversy, we shall
nevertheless list them in logical orders rather than according
to the degree of consensus they command.
(a) The capitalist's
compulsion to accumulate. Capital appears in the form
of accumulated money, thrown into circulation in order to
increase in value. No owner of money capital will engage in
business in order to recuperate exactly the sum initially
invested, and nothing more than that. By definition, the search
for profit is at the basis of all economic operations by owners
of capital.
Profit (surplus-value,
accretion of value) can originate outside the sphere of
production in a precapitalist society. It represents then
essentially a transfer of value (so-called primitive
accumulation of capital); but under the capitalist mode of
production, in which capital has penetrated the sphere of
production and dominates it, surplus-value is currently produced
by wage labour. It represents a constant increase in value.
Capital can only appear in the
form of many capitals, given its very historical-social
origin in private property (appropriation) of the means of
production. ‘Many capitals’ imply unavoidable competition.
Competition in a capitalist mode of production is competition
for selling commodities in an anonymous market. While
surplus-value is produced in the process of production, it is realised
in the process of circulation, i.e. through the sale of the
commodities. The capitalist wants to sell at maximum profit. In
practice, he will be satisfied if he gets the average profit,
which is a percentage really existing in his consciousness (e.g.
Mr Charles Wilson, the then head of the US automobile firm
General Motors, stated before a Congressional enquiry: we used
to fix the expected sales price of our cars by adding 15% to
production costs). But he can never be sure of this. He cannot
even be sure that all the commodities produced will and a buyer.
Given these uncertainties, he
has to strive constantly to get the better of his competitors.
This can only occur through operating with more capital. This
means that at least part of the surplus-value produced will not
be unproductively consumed by the capitalists and their
hangers-on through luxury consumption, but will be accumulated,
added to the previously existing capital.
The inner logic of capitalism
is therefore not only to ‘work for profit’, but also to
‘work for capital accumulation’. ‘Accumulate, accumulate;
that is Moses and the Prophets’, states Marx in Capital,
Vol. I. Capitalists are compelled to act in that way as
a result of competition. It is competition which basically fuels
this terrifying snowball logic: initial value of capital –
accretion of value (surplus-value) – accretion of capital –
more accretion of surplus-value – more accretion of capital
etc. Without competition, the fire of growth would burn out.
(b) The tendency
towards constant technological revolutions. In the
capitalist mode of production, accumulation of capital is in the
first place accumulation of productive capital, or capital
invested to produce more and more commodities. Competition is
therefore above all competition between productive capitals,
i.e. ‘many capitals’ engaged in mining, manufacturing,
transportation, agriculture, telecommunications. The main weapon
in competition between capitalist firms is cutting production
costs. More advanced production techniques and more
‘rational’ labour organisation are the main means to achieve
that purpose. The basic trend of capital accumulation in the
capitalist mode of production is therefore a trend towards more
and more sophisticated machinery. Capital growth takes the dual
form of higher and higher value of capital and of constant
revolutions in the techniques of production, of constant
technological progress.
(c) The capitalists'
unquenchable thirst for surplus-value extraction. The
compulsion for capital to grow, the irresistible urge for
capital accumulation, realises itself above all through a
constant drive for the increase of the production of
surplus-value. Capital accumulation is nothing but surplus-value
capitalisation, the transformation of part of the new
surplus-value into additional capital. There is no other source
of additional capital than additional surplus-value produced in
the process of production.
Marx distinguishes two
different forms of additional surplus-value production. Absolute
surplus-value accretion occurs essentially through the
extension of the work day. If the worker reproduces the
equivalent of his wages in 4 hours a day, an extension of the
work day from 10 to 12 hours will increase surplus-value from 6
to 8 hours. Relative surplus-value accretion occurs
through an increase of the productivity of labour in the
wage-goods sector of the economy. Such an increase in
productivity implies that the equivalent of the value of an
identical basket of goods and services consumed by the worker
could be produced in 2 hours instead of 4 hours of labour. If
the work day remains stable at 10 hours and real wages remain
stable too, surplus-value will then increase from 6 to 8 hours.
While both processes occur
throughout the history of the capitalist mode of production
(viz. the contemporary pressure of employers in favour of
overtime!), the first one was prevalent first, the second one
became prevalent since the second half of the 19th century,
first in Britain, France and Belgium, then in the USA and
Germany, later in the other industrialized capitalist countries,
and later still in the semi-industrialised ones. Marx calls this
process the real subsumption (subordination ) of
labour under capital, for it represents not only an
economic but also a physical subordination of the wage-earner
under the machine. This physical subordination can only be
realized through social control. The history of the capitalist
mode of production is therefore also the history of successive
forms of - tighter and tighter - control of capital over the
workers inside the factories (Braverman, 1974); and of attempts
at realising that tightening of control in society as a whole.
The increase in the production
of relative surplus-value is the goal for which capitalism tends
to periodically substitute machinery for labour, i.e. to expand
the industrial reserve army of labour. Likewise, it is the main
tool for maintaining a modicum of social equilibrium, for when
productivity of labour strongly increases, above all in the
wage-good producing sectors of the economy, real wages and
profits (surplus-value) can both expand simultaneously. What
were previously luxury goods can even become mass-produced
wage-goods.
(d) The tendency
towards growing concentration and centralisation of capital.
The growth of the value of capital means that each successful
capitalist firm will be operating with more and more capital.
Marx calls this the tendency towards growing concentration of
capital. But in the competitive process, there are victors and
vanquished. The victors grow. The vanquished go bankrupt or are
absorbed by the victors. This process Marx calls the
centralisation of capital. It results in a declining number of
firms which survive in each of the key fields of production.
Many small and medium-sized capitalists disappear as independent
business men and women. They become in turn salary earners,
employed by successful capitalism firms. Capitalism itself is
the big ‘expropriating’ force, suppressing private property
of the means of production for many, in favour of private
property for few.
(e) The tendency for
the ‘organic composition of capital’ to increase.
Productive capital has a double form. It appears in the form of constant
capital: buildings, machinery, raw materials, energy, It appears
in the form of variable capital: capital spent on wages
of productive workers. Marx calls the part of capital used in
buying labour power variable, because only that part produces
additional value. In the process of production, the value of
constant capital is simply maintained (transferred in toto
or in part into the value of the finished product). Variable
capital on the contrary is the unique source of ‘added
value’.
Marx postulates that the basic
historic trend of capital accumulation is to increase investment
in constant capital at a quicker pace than investment in
variable capital; the relation between the two he calls the
‘organic composition of capital’. This is both a
technical/physical relation (a given production technique
implies the use of a given number of productive wage earners
even if not in an absolutely mechanical way) and a value
relation. The trend towards an increase in the ‘organic
composition of capital’ is therefore a historical trend
towards basically labour-saving technological progress.
This tendency has often been
challenged by critics of Marx. Living in the age of
semi-automation and ‘robotism’, it is hard to understand
that challenge. The conceptual confusion on which this challenge
is most based is an operation with the ‘national wage bill’,
i.e. a confusion between wages in general and variable capital,
which is only the wage bill of productive labour. A more correct
index would be the part of the labour costs in total production
costs in the manufacturing (and mining) sector. It is hard to
deny that this proportion shows a downward secular trend.
(f) The tendency of the
rate of profit to decline. For the workers, the basic
relation they are concerned with is the rate of surplus-value,
i.e. the division of ‘value added’ between wages and
surplus-value. When this goes up, their exploitation (the unpaid
labour they produce) obviously goes up. For the capitalists,
however, this relationship is not meaningful. They are concerned
with the relation between surplus-value and the totality
of capital invested, never mind whether in the form of machinery
and raw materials or in the form of wages. This relation is the rate
of profit. It is a function of two variables, the organic
composition of capital and the rate of surplus-value. If the
value of constant capital is represented by c, the
value of variable capital (wages of productive workers) by v
and surplus-value by s, the rate of profit will be s/(c
+ v). This can be rewritten as [s/v]/[(c+v)/v]
with the two variables emerging ((c + v)/v
obviously reflects c/v).
Marx postulates that the
increase in the rate of surplus value has definite limits, while
the increase in the organic composition of capital has
practically none (automation, robotism). There will be a basic
tendency for the rate of profit to decline.
This is however absolutely true
only on a very long-term, i.e. essentially ‘secular’, basis.
In other time-frameworks, the rate of profit can fluctuate under
the influence of countervailing forces. Constant capital can be
devalorised, through ‘capital saving’ technical process, and
through economic crises (see below). The rate of surplus-value
can be strongly increased in the short or medium terms although
each strong increase makes a further increase more difficult;
and capital can flow to countries (e.g. ‘Third World’ ones)
or branches (e.g. service sectors) where the organic composition
of capital is significantly lower than in the previously
industrialised ones, thereby raising the average rate of profit.
Finally, the increase in the mass
of surplus-value - especially through the extension of wage
labour in general, i.e. the total number of workers - offsets to
a large extent the depressing effects of moderate declines of
the average rate of profit. Capitalism will not go out of
business if the mass of surplus-value produced increases
‘only’ from £10 to 17 billion, while the total mass of
capital has moved from £100 to 200 billion; and capital
accumulation will not stop under these circumstances, nor
necessarily slow down significantly. It would be sufficient to
have the unproductively consumed part of surplus-value pass e.g.
from £3 to £2 billion, to obtain a rate of capital
accumulation of 15/200, i.e. 7.5%, even higher than
the previous one of 7/100, in spite of a decline of
the rate of profit from 10 to 8.5%.
(g) The inevitability
of class struggle under capitalism. One of the most
impressive projections by Marx was that of the inevitability of
elementary class struggle under capitalism. Irrespective of the
social global framework or of their own historical background,
wage-earners will fight everywhere for higher real wages and a
shorter work day. They will form elementary organisations for
the collective instead of the individual sale of the commodity
labour power, i.e., trade unions. While at the moment Marx made
that projection there were less than half a million organised
workers in at the most half a dozen countries in the world,
today trade unions encompass hundreds of millions of
wage-earners spread around the globe. There is no country,
however, remote it might be, where the introduction of wage
labour has not led to the appearance of worker's coalitions.
While elementary class struggle
and elementary unionisation of the working class are inevitable
under capitalism, higher, especially political forms of class
struggle, depend on a multitude of variables which determine the
rapidity with which they extend beyond smaller minorities of
each ‘national’ working class and internationally. But there
too the basic secular trend is clear. There were in 1900
innumerably more conscious socialists than in 1850, fighting not
only for better wages but, to use Marx’s words, for the
abolition of wage labour and organising working class parties
for that purpose. There are today many more than in 1900.
(h) The tendency
towards growing social polarisation. From two
previously enumerated trends, the trend towards growing
centralisation of capital and the trend towards the growth of
the mass of surplus-value, flow the trend towards growing social
polarisation under capitalism. The proportion of the active
population represented by wage-labour in general, i.e. by the
modern proletariat (which extends far beyond productive workers
in and by themselves), increases. The proportion represented by
self-employed (small, medium-sized and big capitalists, as well
as independent peasants, handicraftsmen, trades-people and
‘free professions’ working without wage-labour) decreases.
In fact, in several capitalist countries the first category has
already passed the 90 per cent mark, while in Marx's time it was
below 50 per cent everywhere but in Britain. In most
industrialised (imperialist) countries, it has reached 80-85 per
cent.
This does not mean that the
petty entrepreneurs have tended to disappear. 10 or 15-20 per
cent out of 30 million people, not to say out of 120 million,
still represents a significant social layer. While many small
businesses disappear, especially in times of economic
depression, as a result of severe competition, they also are
constantly created, especially in the interstices between big
firms, and in new sectors where they play an exploratory role.
Also, the overall social results of growing proletarisation are
not simultaneous with the economic process in and by itself.
From the point of view of class consciousness, culture,
political attitude, there can exist significant time-lags
between the transformation of an independent farmer, grocer or
doctor into a wage-earner, and his acceptance of socialism as an
overall social solution for his own and society's ills. But
again, the secular trend is towards growing homogeneity,
less and less heterogeneity, of the mass of the wage-earning
class, and not the other way around. It is sufficient to compare
the differences in consumer patterns, attitudes towards
unionisation or voting habits between manual workers, bank
employees and government functionaries in say 1900 and today, to
note that they have decreased and not increased.
(i) The tendency
towards growing objective socialisation of labour.
Capitalism starts in the form of private production on a
medium-sized scale for a limited number of largely unknown
customers, on an uncontrollably wide market, i.e. under
conditions of near complete fragmentation of social labour and
anarchy of the economic process. But as a result of growing
technological progress, tremendously increased concentration of
capital, the conquest of wider and wider markets throughout the
world, and the very nature of the labour organisation inside
large and even medium-sized capitalist factories, a powerful
process of objective socialisation of labour is simultaneously
set in motion. This process constantly extends the sphere of
economy in which not blind market laws but conscious decisions
and even large-scale co-operation prevail.
This is true especially inside
mammoth firms (inside multinational corporations, such
‘planning’ prevails far beyond the boundaries of
nation-states, even the most powerful ones!) and inside
large-scale factories; but it is also increasingly true for
buyer/seller relations, in the first place on an inter-firm
basis, between public authorities and firms, and more often than
one thinks between traders and consumers too. In all these
instances, the rule of the law of value becomes more and more
remote, indirect and discontinuous. Planning prevails on a short
and even medium-term basis.
Certainly, the economy still
remains capitalist. The rule of the law of value imposes itself
brutally through the outburst of economic crises. Wars and
social crises are increasingly added to these economic crises to
remind society that, under capitalism, this growing objective
socialisation of labour and production is indissolubly linked to
private appropriation, i.e. to the profit motive as motor of
economic growth. That linkage makes the system more and more
crisis-ridden; but at the same time the growing socialisation of
labour and production creates the objective basis for a general
socialisation of the economy, i.e. represents the basis of the
coming socialist order created by capitalism itself, within the
framework of its own system.
(j) The inevitability
of economic crises under capitalism. This is another of
Marx’s projections which has been strikingly confirmed by
history. Marx ascertained that periodic crises of overproduction
were unavoidable under capitalism. In fact, since the crisis of
1825, the first one occurring on the world market for industrial
goods, to use Marx's own formula, there have been twenty-one
business cycles ending (or beginning, according to the method of
analysis and measurement used) with twenty-one crises of
overproduction. A twenty-second is appearing on the horizon as
we are writing.
Capitalist economic crises are
always crises of overproduction of commodities (exchange
values), as opposed to pre- and post-capitalist economic
crises, which are essentially crises of underproduction of
use-values. Under capitalist crises, expanded
reproduction - economic growth - is brutally interrupted,
not because too few commodities have been produced but, on the
contrary, because a mountain of produced commodities finds no
buyers. This unleashes a spiral movement of collapse of firms,
firing of workers, contraction of sales (or orders) for raw
materials and machinery, new redundancies, new contraction of
sales of consumer goods etc. Through this contracted
reproduction, prices (gold prices) collapse, production and
income is reduced, capital loses value. At the end of the
declining spiral, output (and stocks) has been reduced more than
purchasing power. Then production can pick up again; and as the
crisis has both increased the rate of surplus-value (through a
decline of wages and a more ‘rational’ labour organisation)
and decreased the value of capital, the average rate of profit
increases. This stimulates investment. Employment increases,
value production and national income expand, and we enter a new
cycle of economic revival, prosperity, overheating and the next
crisis.
No amount of capitalists’
(essentially large combines’ and monopolies’)
‘self-regulation’, no amount of government intervention, has
been able to suppress this cyclical movement of capitalist
production. Nor can they succeed in achieving that result. This
cyclical movement is inextricably linked to production for
profit and private property (competition), which imply periodic
over-shooting (too little or too much investment and output),
precisely because each firm's attempt at maximising profit
unavoidably leads to a lower rate of profit for the system as a
whole. It is likewise linked to the separation of value
production and value realisation.
The only way to avoid crises of
overproduction is to eliminate all basic sources of
disequilibrium in the economy, including the disequilibrium
between productive capacity and purchasing power of the ‘final
consumers’. This calls for elimination of generalised
commodity production, of private property and of class
exploitation, i.e. for the elimination of capitalism.
|