As a governmental slogan
‘workers and peasants government’ or ‘workers
governments’ crowns in all cases the program of transitional
demands. Thus it has a general value. The objective of the
transitional program, starting from the struggles and immediate
concerns of the masses, is to bring them, with their given level
of consciousness to the stage of understanding the importance of
taking power; to win them to the perspective of exercizing
power. Any program of transitional demands which aims to avoid
the reformist swamp – which does not want to limit the
struggle to one of reforms to be achieved in the framework of
the capitalist economy, of bourgeois society and the bourgeois
state must be completed with a governmental slogan.
‘Workers and peasants
government’ (or ‘workers government’) expresses this
demand in its most general form.
How
was the seizure of power carried out in Yugoslavia, China and
Vietnam
If we examine the course of
victorious socialist revolutions since the Second World War we
note that by and large they fit into the framework of general
analysis of the Transitional Program of the Fourth International
on the central problem of state power. [1]
In Yugoslavia there
was a coalition government imposed on the Yugoslav CP
by Stalin, Roosevelt and Churchill at the Teheran and Yalta
conferences. The Yugoslav CP leadership accepted this government
with extreme reticence and in its public propaganda. But in
practice it stuck to its strategic perspective, adopted
in 1941, of the CP seizing power. It concentrated its
efforts on the mobilization and organization of the poor peasant
masses from the beginning of the 1941 insurrection, and of the
urban masses (we are obviously talking here of organization
and not self-organization) from the liberation of Belgrade,
Zagreb and Ljubljana.
On the 21st November 1944, all
the companies and wealth of the Germans and their collaborators
were confiscated and from that day on the nationalizations
already included 82% of Yugoslav industry. When the
coalition government was set up, the Popular Front, whose
president was Tito, and which had more than 7 million members
organized in local structures (right down to neighborhood
level), was formed. The latter recognized the leading role of
the Communist Party and in fact controlled the country’s
political life. Given all this, given the fact that the National
Liberation Army had more than ½ a million members, was the only
armed force in the country and was entirely controlled by the
CP, we can say that Yugoslavia was then already a workers state.
This was definitively consolidated after the 1945 referendum on
the monarchy the bourgeois ministers had just been token
figureheads without real power. [2]
The Chinese revolution
went through a very similar development to that of the Yugoslav
revolution. The Maoist faction which led the Chinese CP from
1934 had drawn its own conclusions from the defeat of the Second
Chinese revolution in 1927. The lessons it drew were neither
those drawn by the Stalinist faction nor by the Trotskyist
current. This conclusion can be summarized in a simple formula:
avoid 1929-style disasters by forming an armed force
independent of the bourgeoisie, under the exclusive leadership
of the Chinese CP. This was a central strategic orientation
established as early as 1934 or even from 1929.
True, this army was essentially
made up of peasants (but not under peasant leadership or with a
peasant strategic perspective). True, this strategic approach to
the seizure of power through armed struggle was at times
(especially in 1937-38 and 1945-46) sugar-coated in public
propaganda statements which accepted and urged (on the express
orders of Stalin) a coalition with Chiang Kai-shek. True too,
from the programmatic and theoretical point of view, the Maoist
faction for a long time held an intermediate line between the
objective of the democratic revolution (resulting in a
bourgeois-democratic republic with the maintenance of capitalist
property) and that of the dictatorship of the proletariat
resulting in not only the destruction of the bourgeois state and
the disarming of the bourgeoisie, but also in the suppression of
capitalist property. This ‘intermediate’ line was codified
in the theory of the ‘new democracy’ and a ‘state that is
neither bourgeois nor proletarian,’ but this was mitigated by
the constant affirmation of the leading role of the Communist
Party, presented as a proletarian party which had to lead the
peasantry. This line sowed enormous confusion in the minds of
Chinese Communists and especially among all Communists in Asia
(beginning with the unfortunate Aidit and the Indonesian CP,
which paid for their tail-endism of theoretical Maoism, with a
million dead) – as well as on other continents. All these
statements and deeds are manoeuvers and confusion which should
be condemned and not excused, in spite of the victory of the
Chinese revolution. These manoeuvers and confusion are not what
made victory possible. On the contrary victory was achieved in
spite of them. Furthermore such lack of clarity played a
nefarious role by holding back, or even preventing victory in
other countries.
But when all this is duly
noted, as materialists we must still recognize that in reality,
despite their opportunism and theoretical/political confusion
the Maoists disarmed the bourgeoisie, destroyed the bourgeois
state and generally expropriated the big bourgeoisie. This was
done in the 1938 (Yenan) to 1950 period, in a series of
territorial, not political stages. The Peoples Republic of China
proclaimed on November 1st 1949 on the Tien An-Men square in
Peking was, and remains, a dictatorship of the proletariat –
something which the Maoists denied at the time but admitted
later. A state defined as a ‘democracy of a new type’ has
never existed in real life. From 1938 to 1949-50 there was
territorial dual power in China – on one side a bourgeois
state and army in decomposition but still surviving in the
territory controlled by the Kuomintang, and on the other an
incipient workers state in the territory controlled by the
People’s Liberation Army. After 1949-50 only one state existed
in the country a dictatorship of the proletariat with deep-going
bureaucratic deformations from birth (a bourgeois state still
survives today in Taiwan).
In order to ‘discover’
between 1949 and 1953 a ‘workers and peasants government’ in
China distinct from a dictatorship of the proletariat
bureaucratized from birth, you have to overestimate the real
power of these bourgeois hostages, in other words to mistake
appearance, or even worse misleading propaganda, for reality. [3]
You end up with an insoluble theoretical problem. It was this
state formed in 1949 and this army (which from 1949-50
controlled all mainland China) that went to war against American
and international imperialism in Korea, supported (certainly
with sectarian, adventurist, inadmissible and ineffective
methods) the extension of the socialist revolution towards South
Korea, supported (and saved) the Vietnamese revolution after the
big offensive of French imperialism against the liberated
territory of the North in 1947-48, confiscated capitalist
property in stages and eliminated nearly all private peasant
property in successive waves.
You get lost in an absurd
paradox if you claim that a bourgeois state or a ‘peasant
government’ (or one dominated by the peasantry) can, without
any discontinuity, (the Chinese CP of 1953 is not in any way
different from what it was in 1948) carry out such an
anti-capitalist undertaking.
Right from the beginning of
1950 in other words in a shorter period than after October 1917
in Russia – exactly as Trotsky had predicted something like
65% of all Chinese industrial capital and 80% of modern
industrial capitalism were nationalized. These nationalizations
preceded the land reform in the South of the country. So where
is the ‘democratic phase?’ It is not possible to wriggle out
of it with the argument that there was no total
abolition of bourgeois property something that neither Trotsky
nor any serious Marxist has ever proposed.
The case of the Vietnamese
revolution is once again similar to that of Yugoslavia and
China. The Ho Chi-Minh leadership had a clear orientation to the
seizure of power resulting from the armed struggle under its
exclusive leadership right from the beginning of 1945, and
possibly even before this date. But it hesitated on its
definition of the precise class content of the state and economy
which would emerge from this seizure of power. Furthermore it
was placed in such a difficult military situation through the
successive (and combined) aggressions it suffered from French,
Japanese, British, the French again and American imperialism
etc. that we have to be careful not to interpret tactical,
territorial military retreats – made after the 1946 attacks on
Haiphong and Hanoi and during the 1954 Geneva agreements as a long-lasting
political and social compromise (i.e. maintenance of
bourgeois property or ‘bourgeois order’). Certain sectarian
Trotskyists ‘pinned’ such intentions on the Vietnamese
leadership. The latter clearly did not have such a project.
History has already rendered its judgement on this. The
balance-sheet of the official line of the Fourth International
regarding the interpretation of the 1954 and 1974 agreements is
fortunately much more positive than that of the sectarian
tendencies inside and outside our ranks.
Again was there a ‘workers
and peasants government’ distinct from the dictatorship of the
proletariat in Vietnam? In North Vietnam this was obviously not
the case. There was an anti-imperialist war combined with a
civil war (the latter was less extensive than in the South given
the weakness of the local bourgeoisie). When victory was
achieved in the North and the Democratic Republic of Vietnam set
up in Hanoi, there was dictatorship of the proletariat albeit
bureaucratized from birth (less than in China, but to what
degree? That is the subject of a separate discussion inside the
Fourth International). As for South Vietnam where there was a
long civil war it seems to us impossible to prove in reality,
and contradictory from a theoretical point of view, to say that
there was a ‘workers and peasants government’ distinct from
the dictatorship of the proletariat between the fall of Saigon
and the expropriation of the Cholon Chinese comprador
bourgeoisie. [4]
Right after the fall of Saigon a
fusion took place in practice between the Hanoi state
apparatus and the new state in the South. If the state that
emerged from the fall of Saigon was a workers state, the
‘workers and peasants government’ of South Vietnam is
synonymous with the dictatorship of the proletariat –
bureaucratized from the beginning.
How was the
seizure of power carried out in Cuba and Nicaragua?
The Cuban and Nicaraguan cases
are different from those of the USSR, China, Yugoslavia and
Vietnam. In those two countries there were authentic people’s
revolutions (unlike in Eastern Europe where society and the
state were structurally assimilated to the USSR through
essentially military bureaucratic means without a real
people’s revolution). But these people’s revolutions
resulted in the destruction of the dictatorships’ armies while
leaving intact part of the bourgeois state. There was a
transitional period of coalition government with real
bourgeois forces (not simple ‘hostages’) both in Cuba and
Nicaragua. But in both countries revolutionary forces had a
hegemonic role.
In both cases the dictatorship
of the proletariat was in the process of being established
but at that time had not been definitively installed. Whereas
the October revolution established the dictatorship of the
proletariat by a single event in Cuba, as in China and
Vietnam, it emerged through a progressive process of
dual power (territorial in China and Vietnam, sui generis
in Cuba) and not by a single resolute blow struck in favour of
the proletariat.
But we have to be even more
precise, the FSLN and the state power it represents in
this situation of sui generis dual power, incarnates
neither a ‘bourgeois state,’ nor a ‘two-class
government’ nor a ‘popular front,’ but a dictatorship
of the proletariat, a workers state in the process of being
constituted but which has not yet definitively triumphed
over its enemies on the social-political terrain.
In any case nothing justifies
distinguishing a phase of ‘workers and farmers government’
from a phase of dictatorship of the proletariat in Cuba or
Nicaragua any more than it justifies seeing such a separate
phase in Yugoslavia, China or Vietnam. In the 6th World Congress
resolution and the Fourth International Reunification Congress
documents (7th World Congress), such a distinction was not
introduced to characterize the victory of the Cuban Revolution.
It should be further noted that
the 6th World Congress resolution on the birth of the Cuban
workers state points out that while the Cuban state became a
workers state after October 1960 (the Cuban leadership sets the
transformation date at the end of August 1960):
“... on the level of
political leadership, the evolution has been much more one of
form than anything fundamental, real power being in the hands
of the Ejercito Rebelde and the Fidelista team, even
during the period of sui generis dual power going
from the seizure of power to the fall of Urrutia.”
The same remark can be
evidently applied to Nicaragua. We must not underestimate the
reality of the bourgeois state in Cuba before the revolution
much more solid than Somoza’s dictatorship where there was
only a clique of gangsters linked to the army. But, we have to
recognize that capitalist underdevelopment poses
specific problems that further accentuates the possibility of
de-synchronization between the destruction of the political
power of the ruling classes and the destruction of their
economic power. This de-synchronization was even foreseen by
Marx and Engels if we look at their first formulations on the
dictatorship of the proletariat in the Communist
Manifesto. Trotsky makes the following point in Permanent
Revolution:
The possibility of success in
this struggle is of course determined to a large extent by the
role of the proletariat in the economy of the country’ and
consequently by the level of its capitalist development.
This’ however’ is by no means the only criterion. No less
important is the question whether a far-reaching and burning
problem ‘for the people’ exists in the country, in the
solution of which the majority of the nation is interested,
and which demands for its solution the boldest revolutionary
measures. Among problems of this kind are the agrarian
question and the national question, in their varied
combinations. With the acute agrarian problem and the
intolerable national oppression in the colonial countries,
the [emphasis added] young and relatively small proletariat
can come to power [emphasis added] on the basis of a national
democratic revolution sooner than the proletariat of an
advanced country on a purely socialist basis ... A country
can become ‘ripe’ for the dictatorship of the proletariat
not only before it is ripe for the independent construction of
socialism, but even before it is ripe for far-reaching
socialization measures [emphasis added]. (The
Permanent Revolution [New York: Pathfinder 1969],
pp.254-5).
The separate
workers and peasants government stage extended to all capitalist
countries, including the imperialist countries.
Comrade Jack Barnes’ report For
a Workers and Farmers Government in the United States (International
Internal Discussion Bulletin, Volume 18, Number 5, June
1982) widens the differences inside the Fourth International by
bringing into the debate tactical questions concerning the
overthrow of capitalism in the imperialist countries. The
intrinsic dialectics of his line of argument remorselessly
operates. After having attacked the theory of the permanent
revolution and the Marxist theory of the state, the SWP
leadership majority is now attacking a substantial part of the Transitional
Program.
As was already the case with
Comrade Doug Jenness’ article [5],
Comrade Jack Barnes’ report thoroughly muddles up the
question. He leaps from the immediate tasks of the revolutionary
government in Nicaragua to those of a similar government in the
United States, in other words from an extremely underdeveloped
country to the most developed imperialist country in the world.
He mixes up the expropriation of the big bourgeoisie with the
expropriation of the bourgeoisie “as a whole,” and even the
“total” collectivization of agriculture. He lumps together
the NEP, an economic policy carried out by the Bolsheviks under
the dictatorship of the proletariat, with a policy of
maintaining a significant private sector without the
dictatorship of the proletariat under the predominance of
capitalist property. Let’s try and unravel all this tangle.
Comrade Jack Barnes explicitly
extends the idea of a “necessary workers and peasants
government stage” distinct from the dictatorship of
the proletariat to all the capitalist countries:
... what is a workers and
farmers government? ... the first form of government that can
be expected to appear as the result of a successful
anti-capitalist revolution.
Not just in some
countries, not just in backward countries, not just
with inadequate leaderships, but “the first form of
government that can be expected to appear as the result of a
successful anti-capitalist revolution.” Period.
... a workers and farmers
government is independent of the bourgeoisie, but at
the same time still stands on capitalist economic
relations.
Joe wrote that a workers and
farmers government begins “on the basis of the capitalist
economy and even part of the capitalist state structure.
This is the conclusion that
we had reached by 1978, as a result of thinking about and
generalizing the lessons from workers and farmers governments
established since World War II ... (Barnes, Workers and
Farmers Government, pp.5-6.)
Comrade Jack Barnes tries, with
some difficulty, to insinuate (ibid., pp.12-13)
that Trotsky would have indeed implicitly shared the revisionist
ideas of the SWP majority leadership on the workers and peasants
government. But Trotsky had explicitly rejected this in 1937.
This is borne out by the following extract from his writings:
I just want to say something
here on the slogan ‘workers and peasants government.’ We
always argued against this formulation when the Stalinists
counterposed it to the ‘workers government’ and to the
‘dictatorship of the proletariat.’ At the same time we
accepted the label of ‘workers and peasants government’
for the Soviet government. Everything depends on the real
content given to this formulation in function of the
situation, the policy and party in question.
We can very well accept the
slogan of workers and peasants government in Spain as a common
base with the POUMist and anarchist workers. But this slogan
has to be immediately turned back against the POUM leaders.
Workers and peasants government? Okay. But we must then begin
by kicking the bourgeoisie, who exploits the workers and
peasants, out of the government. Workers and peasants
committees should be set up etc. In this way we will be able
to take this popular slogan away from the POUM leaders by
giving it a clearly revolutionary meaning, in other
words, the ‘dictatorship of the proletariat.’ (Leon
Trotsky, The Workers and Peasants government, 26th
May 1937, translated from the French Oeuvres,
Letter to Jean Rous, Volume 14, pp.73-74,
our emphasis.)
To defend his far-fetched
thesis, Comrade Jack Barnes without saying so clearly and
frankly implicitly assumes:
- that before the seizure of
power there has never been a broad sector of the proletariat
already conscious of the necessity of expropriating big
capital, i.e. a deep-going anti-capitalist consciousness;
- that there will never be
generalized and centralized soviets before the seizure of
power;
- that the workers will never
occupy and take over the main workplaces (or even most
workplaces), restart production under their control within a
revolutionary process before this seizure of power;
- that a revolutionary party
actually working for the dictatorship of the proletariat
will never win over a majority of wage earners (in other
words the absolute majority of the working population
in the industrialized countries) inside the workers councils
and/or peoples councils mentioned in ‘c)’, before the
seizure of power;
- that this seizure of power
by the soviets (workers councils and people’s councils)
will never coincide with the destruction of the bourgeois
army and the other repressive forces of the bourgeoisie,
with the destruction of the bourgeois state apparatus, with
the general arming of the workers and with the beginning of
the building of a state of an entirely new type, as outlined
in Lenin’s State and Revolution, that is
a state of the dictatorship of the proletariat.
For it cannot be denied that if
these five conditions, or most of them, exist, the power
emerging from the victorious insurrection has already destroyed
the bourgeois state, confiscated most capitalist property and
entered a head-on confrontation with the national and
international bourgeoisie. Consequently it is difficult to see
in what sense this workers and peasants government (or workers
government) would be different from the dictatorship of the
proletariat, and what supplementary ‘stage’ it would have to
go through in order to reach the latter.
It is easy to understand why
Comrade Jack Barnes is embarrassed in openly and frankly
recognizing the presuppositions that underpin his thesis. For
the implication is that he must pronounce dead and buried not
just two chapters of the Transitional Program
(on the theory of the Permanent Revolution and on the Workers
and Peasants Government) but at least seven of these chapters,
if not the whole program. Just refer to the following passage
from the chapter The expropriation of separate groups of
capitalists: “Only a general revolutionary upsurge of the
proletariat can place the complete expropriation of the
bourgeoisie on the order of the day. The task of
transitional demands is to prepare the proletariat to solve this
problem.” (Trotsky, Transitional Program,
p.122, our emphasis.) (i.e., the general expropriation of
the bourgeoisie and not just some sort of ‘mixed economy’
– EM)
Need we also recall the
following chapter on the Soviets:
If the factory committee
creates a dual power in the factory, then the soviets initiate
a period of dual power in the country.
Dual power in its turn is the
culminating point of the transitional period. Two
regimes, the bourgeois and the proletarian, are irreconcilably
opposed to each other. Conflict between them is inevitable.
The fate of society depends on the outcome. Should the
revolution be defeated, the fascist dictatorship of the
bourgeoisie will follow. In case of victory, the power of
the soviets, that is, the dictatorship of the proletariat and
the socialist reconstruction of society will arise. (Ibid.,
pp.136-137, our emphasis.)
It is worth pointing out that
there is no mention here of any sort of “intermediate stage”
of the workers and peasants government distinct from the
dictatorship of the proletariat. But then Trotsky, Cannon and
other participants at the Founding Congress of the Fourth
International were undoubtedly “hopeless sectarians”
(Chicago speech).
It is true there were no
soviets and no seizure of power by the soviets in the Cuban,
Nicaraguan, Yugoslav, Chinese and Vietnamese revolutions.
But the fact that these five
revolutions did not reproduce the course of the October
revolution is hardly a sufficient basis for founding hypotheses
on future revolutions. Indeed it is an especially
inadequate basis for proclaiming in a peremptory fashion today
that there will be always and everywhere “a workers and
peasants government stage” distinct from the
dictatorship of the proletariat, particularly since this stage
did not even exist in Yugoslavia, China, Vietnam, Cuba and
Nicaragua.
In order to identify the objective
and subjective roots of the particular course taken by the
revolution in the five countries where it has been victorious
since the Second World War, we have to be clear about the
socio-economic and political specificities of these
countries in relation to the rest of the world:
- The proletariat as a class
– not to speak of the industrial proletariat was not a
majority of the working population in any of these
countries.
- The proletariat was not the
main spearhead in the revolutionary process in any of these
countries (this does not at all mean that it did not play a
very important role in Yugoslavia after the
military victory and before the establishment of
the dictatorship of the proletariat; or in Cuba through the
success of the second general strike for the overthrow of
Batista and the role played by the sugar plantation
proletariat in the course of the revolutionary process).
- The workers did not set up
soviet-type structures in the course of this process in any
of these countries.
- The parties which led these
revolutions did not have a clear programmatic line on the
establishment of the dictatorship of the proletariat (with
the exception of the Yugoslav CP) and in any case, they did
not systematically educate and prepare the masses for this
objective. But they had a conscious perspective of seizing
power, although the precise class character of this
power remained vague (except in the case of Yugoslavia and
partially in Nicaragua).
Looking at the world today in
the light of these conditions what can we observe?
The first two conditions hold
neither for the imperialist countries, nor for the main
semi-industrialized dependent countries, nor for the big
majority of the bureaucratized workers states. A revolution in
any of these countries without the participation of the
majority of the urban and rural proletariat would be a
minority revolution, a ‘Blanquist’ putsch, of the sort
Lenin, Trotsky and their comrades always rejected in their
struggle for a mass Communist International.
The fourth condition
presupposes that one has declared the effort to build the Fourth
International a definitive failure i.e., the fight to build a
new revolutionary leadership of the proletariat with a
clear perspective of the seizure of power and the
self-organization of the toiling masses in structures of a
soviet type.
If that is Comrade Barnes’
opinion then let him say so openly. At least we would know what
we were really discussing.
As for the third condition –
the most important of the four -it actually means projecting the
Cuban and Nicaraguan model “onto” the rest of the world,
overlooking the lessons of the totality of revolutionary
experiences since the October revolution, and arbitrarily
deriving these lessons from only five cases of revolutionary
victories which, as if by chance, took place in more or less
underdeveloped countries.
The real
record of the world revolution 1917-1982
Now the real record of the
world revolution over the 65 years since the victory of the
October 1917, socialist revolution in Russia is a balance sheet
that has to include at least 30 countries and not just five.
Furthermore in the majority of these cases, in fact in all
cases where these revolutions spread from the town to the
country and not vice-versa, that is, in all countries where the
urban proletariat was the main motor-force, the main themes of
the Russian Revolution have been confirmed. Strikes with factory
occupations and the self-organization of the proletariat played
a central and determinant role.
This was the case with: the
Finnish revolution in 1918, Germany and Austria in 1918-19,
Hungary in 1919, the beginning of the Italian revolution in
1920, Germany 1923, Spain in 1936-37. June ’36 in France, the
postwar revolutionary crisis in Italy culminating in the 14th
July 1948 events, May ’68 in France, the Italian “Hot
Autumn” of 1969, the Chilean revolution of 1970-73 and the
Portuguese revolution in 1974-75. As proletarian revolutions the
anti-bureaucratic political revolutions in Hungary 1956,
Czechoslovakia 1968-69 and especially Poland 1980-81 also
confirm this.
To recognize that all these
beginnings of proletarian revolutions had a great number of
common traits with the 1917 Russian revolution (and that of
1905) is not a sign of any “Trotskyist dogmatic
sectarianism” on our part.
It is the product of real life,
real history and experience, just as the real revolutionary
process in Cuba, Nicaragua, Yugoslavia, China or Vietnam is not
a product of ‘revisionism’ but of real life. To deny the
reality of the other revolutionary processes on the pretext they
were not victorious is just as dogmatic, sectarian and
idealistic as to deny the reality of revolutionary victories in
the five countries we have referred to on the basis that the
revolution was not led by a revolutionary Marxist party.
All revolutionary processes
which have shaken bourgeois stability to its foundations since
1917 are part and parcel of the real development of the world
revolution. It is inadmissible from the point of view of
scientific socialism, of Marxism, to exclude one part of that
real development from being part of the laboratory of
examination and experimentation which helps us assess what
will happen in future proletarian revolutions.
(Particularly since the part left out concerns the big majority
of those involved in revolutions and the overwhelming majority
of proletarian participants).
The emergence of soviet-type
structures (or in more general terms: “the dynamic of the
masses towards self-organization”) stems from the basic reality
of proletarian existence. In turn, such forms of
self-organization correspond to the fundamental political
demands of the class struggle once it has reached a certain
level of maturity. That is why this type of body (or the dynamic
towards self-organization) emerges in the imperialist countries,
in the semi-industrialized dependent countries and the
bureaucratized workers states, independently of the different
strategic objectives of these three sectors of the world
revolution. Soviet-type forms of organization do not appear as a
result of the strategic aims of the revolution but because of
the social composition of the majority of people involved.
The proletariat instinctively
turns to soviet-type forms of organization because it is the
only means of forming a united class front against the enemy
or enemies it is fighting. It is the only instrument of
organization and struggle which by definition unites all
wage-earners. Neither the trade unions, nor a united front of
parties (or parties and trade unions) nor a fortiori a
single party (however revolutionary) can attain the degree of
unification of the workers or people’s councils.
It also makes it possible to
integrate into this self-organization all those, male or female,
who don’t work in the capitalist work place.
Moreover, this thesis of the
generalization of the Cuban and Nicaraguan experiences actually
presupposes that the “ultra-leftism,” “impatience,”
“sectarianism,” or, put more crudely, the ‘excesses’ of
the soviets, were the basic reasons for the revolutionary
defeats in Germany, Italy, Spain etc. We categorically reject
such an argument. Our position is that the defeat of these
revolutions is not due to the ‘ultra-leftism’ of the workers
and their experience of ‘self-organization’ but to the
rightist opportunism of the parties leading the workers movement
of these countries, to their refusal to break with bourgeois
order, to smash the bourgeois state. It was due to the absence
of a revolutionary leadership, to the bankruptcy of the
traditional leaderships of the workers movement of these
countries.
Furthermore, the Russian
bourgeoisie, however weak it was compared to the Western
bourgeoisie, was infinitely stronger than the Yugoslav, Chinese,
Cuban, Vietnamese (not to mention the Nicaraguan) bourgeoisies.
Remember Lenin explicitly classified it among the imperialist
bourgeoisies. The Russian urban working class was also much
stronger than the working class of the 5 countries mentioned
above. In such conditions only a higher degree of
self-organization, education and consciousness of the masses as
well as a revolutionary leadership (or leaderships) that is (or
are) programmatically and strategically better equipped than the
leaderships who led the Yugoslav, Chinese, Vietnamese, Cuban and
Nicaraguan revolutions to victory, will be able to bring down a
much stronger and politically experienced enemy that is also far
more capable of engaging in maneuvers including daring maneuvers
to preserve its class power.
Is it
possible to have a mixed economy regime in the course of a
proletarian revolution – neither capitalist nor socialist?
In his article Comrade Jack
Barnes imprudently links the question of the “two-class
government” to that of the non-expropriation of the big (and a
part of the medium-sized) bourgeoisie. In fact he defends the
idea that a “transitional stage” of “workers and farmers
government” before the dictatorship of the proletariat is
generally applicable by arguing that it is impossible to
‘immediately’ expropriate big capital. He does not beat
about the bush, he characterizes the economy of this
transitional stage as a ‘mixed economy’:
There is another sense in
which such a government can be called petty bourgeois, the
only sense that holds true for all of them. That is the fact
that the job such a government must accomplish in establishing
the domination of proletarian economic forms is not
yet done. As long as that job is not completed, there is no
way it can base itself on something different from the
bourgeois economic forms it inherited, even if increasingly
diluted with a “mixture” of the proletarian economic forms
it is heading towards, i.e., state property (Barnes, Workers
and Farmers Government, p.7).
Let’s leave aside the fact
that to characterize not only the Sandinista government but even
Lenin and Trotsky’s government as “ petty-bourgeois” is
the height of arrogant sectarianism. The more serious
implication in our opinion is that the concept of the mixed
economy is the traditional formulation of the social democratic
reformists, taken up again later by Khruschev and the
neo-Stalinists and then by the Eurocommunists. The parallel with
the idea of “advanced democracy” put forward by the Western
European CPs is striking. Revolutionary Marxists have always
stated that a strategy based on an “intermediary” period
during which the economy would stay formally capitalist and the
state bourgeois, although workers would exercize political power
in an “anti-capitalist” way, is utopian in reality and
misleading as propaganda (of course the rhythm and
precise degree of expropriation of the bourgeoisie is something
quite different – it depends on judgements about the
relationship of forces, i.e. as a purely tactical problem).
What exists in reality under
the false term “mixed economy,” in the imperialist countries
and most of the semi-industrialized dependent countries
(including India), is a capitalist economy with a more
or less extensive nationalized sector. Falsely dubbing this
economy “non-capitalist” – as does the CPSU program
adopted at its 22nd Congress – in no way changes this reality.
There is a basic criterion for
deciding on whether a “national” economic system (having
even a slightly stable process of reproduction) is capitalist or
not: does the law of value still basically determine
its motion? Are investments made as a priority in the most
profitable sectors in relation to current prices on the world
market? Does industrial development essentially depend on sector
by sector estimations of profitability? Does the state
systematically block such a tendency by steering the majority of
all investment towards sectors considered as a priority on
the basis of non-profit criteria? Does it maintain full
employment, or progressively try and achieve this objective (the
right to work for everybody), by virtue of its decision-making
power over all investment? Is the economy as a consequence
generally protected against the danger of being drawn into
international capitalist crises? Does this economy continue to
grow when the international capitalist economy declines?
Certainly we do not define the
alternative to the capitalist economy as a socialist
economy. The full and complete achievement of socialism is
impossible in a single country or in a small group of countries.
The real alternative to the capitalist economy, in one or
several countries, before the victory of the world revolution,
or at least its victory in the main industrialized countries, is
not the socialist economy but a largely (or predominantly) socialized
economy, the economy of a transitional period between capitalism
and socialism. In such an economy the law of value no longer
dominates productive activity but continues to influence it.
These economies are not dragged into the storm of capitalist
crises of overproduction, but are affected by their
consequences.
Both forms of economy are possible,
the last 65 years of experience has taught us that. What is
impossible on the other hand is an economy that is regulated and
yet at the same time not regulated by the law of value; where
commodity production prevails and yet does not prevail; an
economy integrated and yet not integrated in the international
capitalist market; and where the state both has and does not
have the decision-making power over overall investment, over its
share-out between the main different sectors of the national
economy and the resulting general level of employment. Such a
‘mixed economy’ is, to paraphrase Lenin, a hollow dream. It
has never existed. It will never exist.
Even if out of necessity, due
to the depth of the crisis in a semi-colonial country and given
the international context, maintaining a dominant private sector
can be politically correct, it still remains the case that the
economic effects of this policy will be difficult to control.
The key question is that such an economic policy must not become
an obstacle to the self-organization and mobilization of the
masses.
While the negative effects are
already evident for the most backward semi-colonial countries
any institutionalization of a “mixed economy” in a
semi-industrialized dependent country, indeed in an imperialist
country, is a dangerous, even blatantly reactionary, utopia. In
the latter countries – with a few exceptions – there is
already a big nationalized sector before the
revolutionary crisis. A long time before the
revolutionary crisis there is already a tradition of demands for
nationalization, even expropriation of the additional sectors of
the economy, by the trade union and workers movement – not to
mention demands for the expropriation of big capital put forward
by revolutionaries in their transitional program. An
“instinctive” dynamic already exists among a significant
sector of the working class to occupy the factories and take
control of the machines, etc., during each mass strike.
In these conditions opposing
the ‘immediate’ expropriations of Big Capital, means
stirring up a process of division of the working class between
the politically advanced and politically backward sectors. In
other words deliberately basing oneself on the most politically
backward sectors. Not only does this mean refusing to take on a
vanguard role in the revolutionary process but it also opens up
the big risk of having to carry out repression against the
vanguard workers, including against the core sectors in defence
of private property!
The only argument put forward
by Comrade Jack Barnes in support of his thesis on the necessity
of a transitional “mixed economy” without expropriating Big
Capital, is that this “immediate” expropriation would cause
economic chaos: “A revolutionary government can’t simply decree
the disappearance of capital. It can try, but it won’t work
and will create needless chaos.” (Barnes, Workers and
Farmers Government, p.6.) “So the workers and farmers
government opens up an entire new dynamic and direction, an
anti-capitalist dynamic and direction. This is not an
instantaneous transformation of the economy; that’s not
feasible.” (Ibid., p.8.)
In reality the argument should
be turned on its head. What causes chaos and economic
collapse in the course of the revolutionary process in
countries with medium industrial development’ and still more
in highly industrial countries is precisely the desperate
attempt by leaders of the mass movement to hang onto a mixed
economy. It is the pursuit of this myth which leads rapidly
to the near total halt of the economy.
Private capitalists stop
investing. They organize the flight of capital on a large scale.
The only valid response is the immediate seizure (indeed this is
a preventive measure) of their factories and their bank
accounts, the state monopoly of foreign trade, the substitution
of public investment for private investment, radical monetary
reform, in other words, the socialization of the economy. If
this is not done, the result is a brutal drop in production,
massive unemployment, shortages, galloping inflation, a decline
in living standards, growing discontent, etc. (it is interesting
that Comrade Barnes hardly mentions unemployment among the
problems with which the workers and peasants government have to
grapple immediately). There is nothing inevitable about all that
except if one thinks it is out of the question to break with the
market economy, to firmly end links with the national and
international bourgeoisie on the economic level, to expropriate
capital. Maintaining the “mixed economy” equals
worsening chaos. Large-scale socialization of the economy equals
positive outcome to the crisis: this is the dilemma.
Comrade Jack Barnes gets the
question confused (just like the new Social-Democrats,
Eurocommunists and Stalinists) by confusing preponderant
socialization of the economy with complete socialization. No
serious-minded person inside the revolutionary movement or the
Fourth International has ever recommended the total
nationalization of the economy 24 hours, 24 weeks or even 24
months after the victory of the socialist revolution in the USA,
Great Britain, France or Germany, and in Poland or the USSR
after the victory of the anti-bureaucratic political revolution.
We are talking about the nationalization of the key sectors of
the economy.
It permits the workers state or
better still the national congress of workers councils (or
soviets) to issue binding instructions and determine the general
development of the economy – to end its subordination
to the needs of profit, the law of value and commodity
production.
There can be no principled
objection to allowing the survival of a private sector of
varying size in small scale industry, for artisans, in the
distribution and certain other service sectors – and of course
in agriculture – once there is the dictatorship of the
proletariat and the economy is regulated by socialist planning
(or even better planned and democratically centralized workers
self-management). But this private sector must be sufficiently
limited and controlled so that it does not go beyond certain
limits. Private accumulation must not be allowed to get the
upper hand over planning, nor the private sector link up with
the world market.
Comrade Jack Barnes reaches the
height of confusion when he mixes up the question of the
“mixed economy” with the NEP in Russia. It is evident for
anybody who knows the writings of Lenin, Trotsky and other
Bolshevik leaders on this that events forced the Bolsheviks
to adopt war communism and was neither the product of their
political project nor an ideal model to follow. For us it is the
ABC that the NEP was a salutary reaction against the excesses of
“war communism.” We could remind Comrade Jack Barnes that
Trotsky stated that he demanded such an NEP since 1919. Let’s
hope he is not also going to challenge Trotsky’s evidence.
But what was the NEP? It
was a tactical retreat by the Russian Communists, made
possible by the fact that the dictatorship of the proletariat
already existed (that is, it did not lead to capitalist
restoration). In other words the Communists already held all
political power, all basic industry, all large-scale commerce,
all the transport system, all foreign trade, all the credit
system was already nationalized. Lenin repeated this dozens of
times. The NEP did not signify a retreat to capitalism precisely
because there was no “mixed economy” in Russia but
a solid base of workers power and the socialized economy. As
against the claims of the Mensheviks, SRs, Social Democrats, and
certain ‘Left’ Communists in the West, the NEP preserved the
possibility of beginning to build a socialist economy and
society (the beginning and not the end). By identifying
“NEP” and “mixed economy,” Comrade Jack Barnes
contradicts all the Leninist analysis of 1920-21 as well as the
real course of USSR history.
Even in these “ideal”
conditions – i.e., its introduction after the consolidation of
the dictatorship of the proletariat in Russia, after several
years the NEP involved major risks for the Soviet economy. After
1923 the ‘scissors effect’ between agricultural and
industrial prices began to make itself felt. From 1923-24 the
problems of stepping up industrialization and the growing
differentiations inside the peasantry were posed. The Kulaks
were in control of a major part of the agricultural surplus –
i.e., the main potential source of funds for primitive socialist
accumulation.
At that time two opposed
political lines existed inside the CPSU. Zinoviev/Stalin/Bukarin
proposed a more or less long term ‘harmonious’ continuation
of the NEP with the peaceful integration of the Kulak
and NEP men into this ‘accumulation’ (particularly through
the mystification of a ‘sale of state bonds’ to the well-off
bourgeois and petty bourgeois sectors, bonds to be used to
finance industrialization). The Left Opposition (which Zinoviev
later supported) predicted an inevitable exacerbation
of the contradictions between the private and socialized sectors
of the soviet economy, a growing tension between the Kulaks
and the workers state, the need to step up industrialization, to
give poor peasants the choice of voluntarily joining the kolkhozes
equipped with agricultural machines and starting with levels of
productivity, production of surplus and peasant family income
higher than those of the kulaks.
Was this battle of Trotsky and
the Left Opposition from 1923 “mistaken,” “sectarian,”
“underestimating the peasantry?” We would like to know
Comrade Jack Barnes’ answer on this one.
If the answer is negative then
what remains of the thesis concerning a long “NEP” period?
Shouldn’t we rather say that by alerting the party and
proletariat to the contradictions and dangers of continuing the
NEP, Trotsky and the Left Opposition saved the USSR from
capitalist restoration? We could also add that the
Zinoviev/Stalin/Bukarin refusal in 1923-24 to adopt the course
proposed by the Opposition was one of the decisive factors
leading to the Soviet Thermidor. It produced a catastrophic
delay in the industrialization of the country, in the
mechanization of agriculture. Pursuing such a policy led to the
kulak ‘supplies strike’ in winter 1928 – which was one of
the factors that triggered off the panic reaction of the
bureaucracy the forced collectivization of agriculture. Didn’t
this in turn result in the brutal decline in workers living
standards, gigantic social tensions throughout society, the
creation of a climate of generalized repression and the
destruction of the final remnants of soviet democracy –
including inside the CPSU?
And if this battle was
sectarian, if Bukarin was right, wouldn’t we have to look
again at the whole role of Trotsky and the Opposition in the
USSR, in the CPSU and the Communist International after 1923?
Wouldn’t it then be necessary to revise even more than seven
chapters of the Transitional Program?
In his December 31, 1982
speech, reproduced in the magazine New International,
No.1, Autumn 1983, Comrade Barnes makes a new 180 degree turn.
He now states (p.76) that a workers and farmers government is
“the first phase of the dictatorship of the proletariat.”
But his contradictions do not become in any way more explicable.
This all has to mean one thing or the other. Either (the first
possibility) the ‘first phase of the dictatorship of the
proletariat’ implies there is already a workers state. If that
is true then what becomes of all the “theoretical
innovations” of these last years? So we can have a
dictatorship of the proletariat without ‘total nationalization
of capitalist property.’ So obviously the socialist revolution
of October 1917 created a workers state and the Chinese
People’s Republic was a workers state bureaucratized from the
time it was born. We deserve at least a self-criticism for the
incredible off-handed way with which Comrade Jack Barnes treats
Marxist theory. The other possibility of course is that the
“first phase of the dictatorship of the proletariat”
coincides with a bourgeois state. Now the state is the
instrument of the ruling class to protect its class rule. A fine
sort of “dictatorship of the proletariat” which is the
instrument of bourgeois class rule!
But Comrade Jack Barnes gets
even more confused. According to Comrade Jack Barnes the Ben
Bella government in Algeria was also a ‘workers and farmers
government.’ However this government was overturned by
Boumedienne’s army which functioned as an army of a bourgeois
state. But now we are asked to see Boumedienne’s army as an
army of the ‘first phase of the dictatorship of the
proletariat’ (since according to Comrade Jack Barnes’ latest
version the ‘workers and farmers government’ equals the
first phase of the dictatorship of the proletariat), i.e. an
army whose class character was identical to that of the
Red Army led by Trotsky. Unless they are perhaps both
identically petty-bourgeois.
The
dictatorship of the proletariat and the small peasantry
A big part of Comrade Jack
Barnes’ report centers on the question of the necessary
alliance between wage-earners (proletarian) and small peasants
in the course of the socialist revolution and the period
following the conquest of power. Starting from the necessity for
such an alliance he proposes a “two-class government” as a
“transition to the dictatorship of the proletariat” in
practically all capitalist countries of the world. According to
Comrade Barnes this alliance is necessary (at least in the
imperialist countries and the most industrialized dependent
countries) not so much because of the still high proportion of
peasants in the population (i.e. among those involved in
revolutionary struggles a criteria we think is correct for all
countries where it is the case) but rather in light of the
importance of agricultural production for the rebuilding of the
economy. The possible exception of Great Britain to this rule is
justified (p.18) by the fact that this country imports the major
part of its foodstuffs (which incidentally is not true anyway).
Such an approach ends in
legitimizing corporatist interests based on “privileged”
jobs, justifying wages increases made up of “special interest
payments.” Instead of representing the interests of the
proletariat and the working masses as a whole, the workers and
peasants government would become a mosaic of particular interest
groups.
But Comrade Barnes retorts,
small peasants are a “specifically exploited class”
(Workers and Farmers Government, p.24). Due to this
they deserve a specific place inside the government. This
argument only deepens the contradiction.
It is true that small peasants
are a specific class distinct from the proletariat; in many
cases they form in effect an exploited class, although not to
the same degree as the proletariat. But precisely because they
constitute a specific class they also have specific
interests apart from those of the proletariat’ not only
in the historic sense of the term (attachment to private
property and all that goes with it), but also in the immediate
meaning of the term (particularly concerning the prices of food
products).
If the government becomes a
“two-class government” where workers and small peasants
“govern together” (Ibid., p.25), who will
arbitrate between these different interests? Will the opinion of
2, 3, 5, or 10% of the working population have the same
influence as 55, 60, 75, or even 80% of the people? What happens
to mass democracy, soviet democracy or socialist democracy?
Governments are made up of
people who outside of totalitarian dictatorship – are
nominated by parties, tendencies, bodies that are supposed to
represent social classes or fractions of social classes. Indeed
Comrade Jack Barnes says more or less the same thing when he
explicitly refers (Ibid., p.25) to “parties
and leaders ... of the working farmers.” But what parties,
which leaders? Is there a single non-bourgeois peasant party or
leader of peasant trade union organizations which are not linked
to the bourgeoisie in the imperialist countries (since we are
discussing the imperialist countries and not just the
semi-colonial or dependent countries!)? Is it these parties and
leaders we want associated with the government or represented
inside the “workers and peasants government?”
Certainly it is inevitable that
during a strong revolutionary upsurge of mass struggles in the
semi-colonial and dependent countries, the poor peasant masses
will form their own bodies of self-organization. It is possible
the same process will be repeated in similar conditions in
certain imperialist countries. These bodies of
self-organization of the non-exploiter working peasantry are the
preferred partners of the proletariat during the
revolutionary process and after its victory. They will be its
allies if the proletarian leadership does not have a
wrong-headed sectarian attitude towards them.
But within this alliance, the
emphasis should not be placed on hypothetical government
participation of representatives of the peasant ‘soviets’ or
‘trade unions’ – a tactical question depending exclusively
on concrete conditions that vary greatly from country to country
and in different periods. Rather we emphasize the right
of poor, non-exploiter, working farmers to freely decide
their own future, and on the absence of any constraint by
the dictatorship of the proletariat over them:
The alliance proposed by the
Proletariat – not to the “middle classes” in general but
to the exploited layers of the urban and rural petty
bourgeoisie, against all exploiters, including those of the
“middle classes” – can be based not on compulsion but
only on free consent, which should be consolidated in a
special “contract.” This “contract” is the program of
transitional demands voluntarily accepted by both sides.
(Trotsky, Transitional Program, p.128.)
In other words, the proletariat
and its revolutionary party (or parties) would commit itself to
respect the private property of small farmers if they
demanded this. But it is not prepared to respect the private
property of the bourgeoisie in order to “calm” the potential
fear of the small landowning farmer (on most occasions such fear
is greatly exaggerated by supporters of class collaboration).
The proletariat and its revolutionary party (or parties) start
from the given consciousness of the working population in the
countryside in order to work out the pace of collectivization of
the economy as a whole. The objective needs of the
socialist revolution, the aspirations and level of consciousness
of the proletariat (wage-earners) are decisive in the
resolution of this question. That is the key difference between
a “two-class government” and the pact (alliance) the
Transitional Program projects between wage-earners and poor
peasants.
This question of a “pact”
is furthermore not at all limited to a single (and hypothetical)
“transitional period” between bourgeois power and the
dictatorship of the proletariat (the transition to the
transition of the transition). It remains relevant for
decades – up to the end of socialist construction in
other words up to the establishment of classless society. Such
is indeed the classic Marxist position admirably expressed by
Frederick Engels in his article, The Peasant question in
France and Germany (November 1894):
... when we are in possession
of state power we shall not even think of forcibly
expropriating the small peasants (regardless of whether with
or without compensation), as we shall have to do in the case
of the big landowners. Our task relative to the small peasant
consists, in the first place, in effecting a transition of his
private enterprise and private possession to cooperative ones,
not forcibly but by dint of example and the offer of social
assistance for this purpose. And then of course we have ample
means of showing to the small peasant a perspective with
advantages that must be obvious to him even today.
We should note that Engels
writes: “when we are in possession of state power.”
He definitively does not say “when there is a two-class
government.” The necessity of a worker-peasant pact which
guarantees the small peasantry the right to freely decide its
future, remains valid for all this long period. Therefore it
does not imply any necessity of some sort of “two-class
government” – unless one wants to institutionalize such a
government for decades.
The distinction we draw between
the worker-peasant alliance and a “two-class government” is
not the result of some sort of “sectarianism” towards the
working peasantry or some sort of primitive “workerism.” It
results from an understanding that the political and economic power
of the bourgeoisie must first of all be broken. It is
necessary to break decisively with the logic of profit
nationally and internationally in order to resolve the working
people’s problems, including peasant concerns which the crisis
of declining capitalism forces upon the laboring masses.
To smash the bourgeoisie’s
power and to open the way to the socialist reconstruction of
society means: all power to the workers, dictatorship of the
proletariat, the power of the workers and peasants councils,
planned self-management, socialist democracy in all fields and
in all countries on a world scale. The worker-peasant alliance
fits into this framework – with inevitable variations
according to the social structure of each country. In no case
can the victory of the socialist revolution, the rule of workers
councils and people’s councils – when it becomes possible
given the overall relationship of forces in a country – be
held back because of the demands of so-called prejudices of the
peasantry, unless one wants to deal a mortal blow to the
interests of the working peasantry.
What progressively emerges in
outline behind Comrade Barnes’ revisionist ideas is a growing
skepticism towards the majority of the proletariat in the
industrialized countries, concerning its capacity to carry out
great anti-capitalist struggles or even to unleash socialist
revolutions. No longer is it the proletarian masses which
provide the pressure of the steam and the party which
concentrates it on a precise objective as Marx, Engels, Lenin,
Trotsky and Rosa Luxemburg thought. [6]
No, it is now the government that represents the steam and the
workers and peasants government “mobilizes” the masses in
order to render them “gradually” capable of expropriating
capital. It seems more and more unthinkable for Comrade Barnes
that these mobilizations and this aspiration for expropriation
could lead to the formation of a workers and peasants
government. Its a curious way of presenting oneself as the
“proletarian tendency” when one so blatantly underestimates
– and even shows contempt – for the proletariat! If this
logic is followed through to the end there is a risk of a total
overturning of the proletarian Marxist conception of the
relationship between the party and the proletariat. At the end
of the road, a manipulative, paternalistic even bureaucratic
conception replaces the proletarian Marxist approach and the
party (party/government) is seen as the sole repository of
‘working-class class consciousness.’ We all know where such
ideas have led the Social Democratic, trade union, Stalinist and
Eurocommunist bureaucracies.
This is not yet the explicit
position of Comrade Jack Barnes. For this reason we continue the
debate with him inside the same international organization
(taking into account the legal curbs represented by the
reactionary Voorhis Act). But there is a risk of arriving at
such conclusions. One would have to be blind and deaf to deny
it.
Footnotes
1.
We have cut out from this part of the article the quotations and
comments concerning the Transitional Programme
and the Tactics Resolution of the Fourth Congress of the
Communist International in order to keep within the
commonly agreed limits for articles going in the IIDB
of 50,000 characters (this is in reply to a document of 300,000
characters).
2.
“... all this served to go beyond the traditional position of
Marxism and the Third International concerning the two stages of
the revolution the bourgeois-democratic revolution and the
socialist revolution (the Yugoslav resolution had already gone
beyond this idea, as Comrade Tito said as early as 1945).”
(Milos Nikolic: The Basic Results of the Development of
Contemporary Marxism, in Socialism in the World,
International Journal of Marxist and Socialist Thought,
Belgrade 1983, VII, No.38, p.58.)
3.
The introduction written by the Intercontinental Press
editors and inserted above my article, In Defense of the
Permanent Revolution, when it was published in that
magazine on the 8th August 1983, contains a blatant case of
falsification. We are reproached for having said: “for more
than two decades we [the reference is unclear] systematically
warned the comrades leading the SWP of the dangers” in its
“sectarian and dogmatic position” on the dictatorship of the
proletariat.
Mandel thus dates the
continuity of his differences with the SWP leadership on such
questions as Cuba and the workers and farmers government to
before the reunification of the Fourth International in 1963.
(IP, Vol.21, No.15, p.446.)
Now if the reader refers to my
article, published in the same IP issue and
also as a special IV supplement 13th June 1983,
he/she can immediately see that it is not at all a case of Cuba but
of China (that the Reunification Congress decided to leave
in suspense) and of the authentically “sectarian and
dogmatic” position the SWP leaders adopted towards the leaders
of the Chinese revolution. We predicted then that they would not
be able to maintain such sectarianism and that it would lead
them to a total change of their positions in the long term. This
is what is happening now. Obstinately refusing to recognize the
dictatorship of the proletariat already existed in China at the
end of 1949. they were led to conclude that the dictatorship of
the proletariat was not even established by the October
revolution! Comrade Jack Barnes himself admits elsewhere in his
report on the workers and peasants government that our forecast
was correct. Since he states that it was the Chinese revolution
which caused them a “gigantic problem.”
4.
See the USec resolution on The Indochinese Crisis
(April 1979) – Indicative vote taken on the general line of
this resolution at 1979 World Congress (11th). (See IP
Special World Congress 1980)
5.
Comrade Doug Jenness’ article, How Lenin Saw the Russian
Revolution, was published in November 1981 in the Militant/International
Socialist Review. My answer, The Debate over the
Character and Goals of the Russian Revolution, was
published in April 1982 in the Militant/ISR.
Comrade Jenness continued the polemic with his Our Political
Continuity with Bolshevism in the June 1982 issue of the Militant/ISR;
my second answer, In Defense of the Permanent Revolution,
dated December 1, 1982, was published in International
Viewpoint’s special supplement of June 13, 1983, and
in Intercontinental Press, with an introduction
by the IP editors, on August 8, 1983.
6.
“Without a guiding organisation the energy of the masses would
dissipate like steam not enclosed in a piston-box. But
nevertheless what moves things is not the piston or the box, but
the steam.” (Leon Trotsky, History of the Russian
Revolution, Sphere edition, Preface, p.17.)
|