The
world watched in disbelief as the media recently discussed
the possibility of Mexico defaulting on its international
debts. We reproduce a talk recently given by Ernest Mandel
to the recent International ‘Debating Socialism’ weekend on
the meaning of the world monetary crisis.
To
understand the threat of a collapse of the world monetary,
credit and banking system, we have to look at the present
economic crisis as a combination of two movements. The first is
the normal business cycle which has an average length of between
five and seven years; the second is a long wave movement which
has been a declining movement since the end of the 1960s or the
beginning of the 1970s and which is interwoven with the normal
cycle. This distinction is necessary for several reasons: to
understand the gravity of the present crisis, but also not to
get carried away by the idea of an uninterrupted linear decline
of output and national income. Trotsky made this same point
during the big depression of 1929-1932; at that time some
Marxists both within the Trotskyist movement, but more often in
other tendencies referring to Marxism, particularly the
Stalinist movement, thought that the crisis would not lead to
any recovery even of a temporary nature through the internal
logic of the capitalist economy. Trotsky opposed this argument
very strongly and events proved him right, for there was an
upturn starting in 1933 or 1934 in the United States, Britain,
Germany and all the big imperialist countries.
There have
now been 21 business cycles since the beginning of what Marx
called the world market for industrial goods in the early 1820s;
if you work out the average length of these business cycles, you
will see it neatly works out to about seven years which was,
incidentally, Marx’s estimate of the length of the cycle in his
own lifetime. In the twentieth century, the period of
imperialism and especially in the period of late capitalism, the
cycle has become a little less long: some five or six years. As
the present recession started, say, in 1980, it is to be
expected that some slight recovery will take place around the
end of this year or the beginning of next year. This will mean
that production will pick up a couple of per cent as will
national incomes and gross national products.
This is of
importance from the view of short-term trade union strategy as
it is generally easier for workers to fight back against attacks
on their standard of living or unemployment under conditions of
even modest upturn, and this will probably develop in a series
of imperialist countries. But while the normal succession of
business cycles continues, it is important to see that this
happens within the framework of a declining or stagnating long
wave and that therefore recoveries are short, recessions are
longer and deeper, and, in particular, unemployment continues to
grow even during the periods of recovery. It is now generally
predicted by nearly all bourgeois and reformist experts that
unemployment will continue to grow into the second half of the
1980s, if not even longer. The basic reason for this lies in
the very nature of investment during this whole long wave:
essentially rationalisation investment, i.e., investment which
destroys more jobs than it creates. This is linked with a long
term upswing in the average productivity of labour as the third
technological revolution proceeds, especially in its present
microchip phase which is abolishing jobs not just in industry
but also in the public service sectors which had been the
largest employment growth areas in the previous decades:
banking, trade, insurance, state administration, health,
education, and even the leisure industry.
While the
productivity of labour grows faster than the increase in output,
even if output grows, unemployment grows. We are faced,
therefore, with the prospect of huge-scale unemployment in the
capitalist countries: even leaving aside unemployment in the
so-called Third World and looking at the Western countries and
Japan alone, unemployment is now about 30 million compared to 20
million during the recession of 1974/5 and 10 million in the
recession of 1970. By 1985 it will grow to 35 million and in
the next recession which will certainly come before the end of
the 1980s, it will probably reach as high as 40 million, which
is close to the level of the 1929-1932 crisis; several Western
countries already have unemployment higher than it was at that
time in absolute figures though not as a percentage of the
population.
In the
United States, unemployment in now officially 11 million; trade
union figures put it at 13 million, and if you adjust these to
include women who have been forced out of the labour market by
the non-availability of jobs, it is nearer to 15 million. Even
this figure does not tell the whole truth because one must also
consider the duration of unemployment: in the United States the
situation is different from that in Europe and Japan because the
turnover in jobs, and thus the turnover in unemployment, is much
larger than in these countries. Some recent estimates published
in the USA suggest that out of a total 90-95 million salary
earners and unemployed people, only 60 million had a permanent
job in the second half of 1981 and the first half of 1982. One
third of the labour force were, while not unemployed, not
permanently employed but in and out of work, working perhaps for
two months, then being two months on the dole, then finding
another job and so on.
The
Monetary Crisis
This, then,
is the backdrop to the present monetary crisis. Let us now look
at its character and how it relates to the post-war boom. The
big mistake which is made by most people who try to interpret
the financial crisis is that they detach in a completely
artificial and unscientific way the present monetary crisis from
what went before. On the contrary, as we have argued many
times, everything that happened after World War Two led towards
this kind of monetary crisis. The post-war boom was essentially
inflationary fuel: to use a metaphor that I have used many times
(and is borrowed from Winston Churchill), one can say that the
Western World floated towards prosperity on an ocean of debts,
of credits and bank money inflation; and of course if you have a
constant and cumulative build-up of this kind, at some point it
explodes. Inflation grows from half a per cent to one per cent,
from one per cent to two, from two to three, and eventually at
some point an explosion is inevitable. So from a purely
technical point of view one can say that the origin of the
present financial crisis lies in the permanent inflation of the
previous 25 years of expansion which created the momentum for
the destruction of monetary stability and which at a certain
point stopped providing the fuel for continued expansion and
started acting as a brake upon it.
To give
just one example of how this happened, probably the gravest
effect of cumulative inflation for the capitalist system was the
impossibility of seriously planning medium and long-term
investment projects. This led to an abandonment, or at the very
least a severe curtailing, of such projects which has been one
of the main causes of the turnabout of the general economic
climate. Every single one of the major investment projects
started at the end of the 1960s and beginning of the 1970s, from
Concorde to Ariane to the new nuclear power stations in the
United States and Europe, had final costs not 10 per cent or 15
per cent but 100, 150 or 200 per cent higher than originally
planned. No capitalist firm in the long run can live with this
sort of situation: you make investment and expansion plans, you
start building new plants and then you find that you have to pay
twice or three times as much as you had initially forecast. The
result is either that you will cancel the project, possibly
leaving unusable a half-built plant, or complete it but make
tremendous losses as happened with Concorde.
This was
far more instrumental in curtailing investment in the long term
than any wage explosion, any increase in nominal or even real
wages, which played a role certainly in making things more
difficult for the capitalist class but only a partial and
subsidiary role. So, when we say that monetarism represents
some sort of turn in capitalist strategy, or at least in the
economic policy of the main capitalist governments, this is
certainly true; but it should not be seen as some sort of
conspiracy -- there is an element of aggression towards the
working class and there are elements of long term bourgeois
class objectives being followed, and I will return to this later
on, but this is not the central point. The capitalists are in
business to make profits not to attack the working class:
attacks on the working class are only ways of defending or
increasing profits. If the capitalists stop investing, it is
not because they are scoundrels who deliberately wish to create
unemployment but because investment is not profitable for them.
There is no class interest, no power on earth, that will stop a
capitalist from making profitable investments; they are not that
class conscious, not that idealistic, not willing to sacrifice
their private interests for the global interests of their
class. But if they cannot profit, and indeed may even make
losses, then there is no preaching by any government, either
right wing or left wing which can make them invest. They will
have to be shown that investment will be profitable before it
will start to pick up again. So, if monetarism represents a
turn, it was not primarily caused by political or ideological
considerations but because tackling inflation became a priority
from the point of view of defending profitability.
Now this,
as I have said, is purely technical. The problem appeared to be
a monetary problem, a problem of balance of payments deficits,
of rising industrial costs and consumer indices getting out of
hand. It was addressed by restricting money circulation and
money quantity, making money dear by putting up interest rates,
and so forth; the details need not concern us here.
But there
is also a more substantive element which is much more important
from a Marxist point of view for understanding where we are
coming from, where we are now, and where we are going. In the
period of capitalist decay starting with the First World War,
and especially in the period of late capitalism starting with
the Second World War, there are intrinsic reasons why the system
through its own inner forces cannot ensure long-term profound
expansion. These internal reasons relate to an excess of
capital and a declining rate of profit from the long-term point
of view, and express themselves in a very clear way on two
fields. First, the internal resources of the system do not
allow markets to grow and profits to grow at a sufficient rate
to ensure even a high rate of unemployment, let alone full
employment, of existing industrial capacity and existing labour
power. If the system is left to itself, without outside
intervention, without state intervention, there will be
permanent excess capacity and permanent unemployment. One of
the merits of Lord Keynes, and he had his merits, was to
understand this fact. He was not the first to do so; many
Marxists had explained before him that this was a necessary
feature of declining, as opposed to rising, capitalism.
The
function of inflation and neo-Keynesian politics was essentially
to overcome this difficulty. There is a big mythology which has
been created by bourgeois ideologues, and unfortunately by some
ideologues of the labor movement, too, about the origins of
inflation. It is not true that the arms race is the main cause
of inflation. From the point of view of facts and figures,
two-thirds of the debts created in the post-war expansion period
were not state debts but private debts; private debts grew twice
as fast as state debts. These private debts were of two kinds:
consumer and corporate debts.
A big part
of the post-war boom in consumer goods was a credit boom. Hire
purchases, of cars and to a lesser extent of consumer durables,
and above all home loans fuelled the boom. Company debts also
exploded at the end of the Second World War and especially
during the 1960s, creating a situation today where many
companies are hovering on the edge of bankruptcy -- often you
can not tell if they are bankrupt or not. They could go over
the edge from one day to the next.
I am not
referring to small firms but some of the major multinationals.
There are probably 10 or 20 of the top 100 companies in that
situation today. This huge debt explosion created an expanding
market and greater investment opportunities and hence the
conditions for the long term boom. But this was fuelled by
debts and not paid for by real resources. There was a
considerable accumulation of debts in the world capitalist
system which was further accelerated after 1973 by the creation
of petrodollars. The banks took large deposits from the
oil-exporting countries and used them as loans to firms or
states for profit. There is an inner logic between the
restraints, the limits, of normal, internal, capitalist
expansion and the plethora of capital and the excess capacity
and growing unemployment.
The
threat of credit collapse
Now we can
see a declining capitalism, with growing difficulties for self
expansion, needing the artificial inflation of markets, allied
to investment via debts. Here we have the essential and final
links in the analysis. The form the inflation has taken has
been an increasing quantity of money -- bank notes and short
term deposits -- floating around. This could be stopped very
easily. A deflationary government policy would bring it to
zero, but at a terrible price of condemning large parts of
industry to bankruptcy. It is a technical possibility, but even
if monetary inflation is stopped, the debts remain unpaid.
Actually the more stable money becomes so the burden of debts
weighs more heavily. By calculating on inflation the
capitalists thought they could get richer through becoming more
and more in debt. In the short-term some did, but this was a
foolish long-term assessment. It was an easy trick. You obtain
loans at a rate of interest of 10 per cent while the rate of
inflation is 15 per cent and the rate of profit 20 per cent,
hence the more money you owe, the richer you become. This is
fine as long as all things remain equal, but if the rate of
interest rises to 20 per cent and rate of profit falls to 10 per
cent, then you become poor. Monetary policies cannot sweep away
the decline in profits or the accumulating debt charges which
are weighing down the capitalist classes and the states
worldwide.
The threat
of a credit collapse takes the specific form of a huge
accumulation of debts via different agents. Today on a world
scale the banks are owed more than $1000 billion and there is
the danger that some of these debtors will be unable to pay back
their debts. Who are these debtors? There are two broad
categories -- governments, and private firms and households.
By
government we mean all governments. There is a myth that it is
only the Third World countries which have huge debts. This is
not true. The Danish and Belgian governments are nearly
bankrupt while the British and Italian are not far behind.
Overall, these governments have debts totaling around $500
billion.
The debts
of private firms are also very substantial. Some firms owe more
than governments. Chrysler has debts approaching $3 billion,
International Harvester and Massey Ferguson $1.5-2 billion,
etc. Overall, the total runs to hundreds of billions of
dollars.
Household
debts, especially in the Anglo-Saxon countries, have a similar
amplitude. It has not been such a problem in France and Italy
because of different consumer habits during the past 25 years.
Nevertheless,
everywhere
mortgages, which are a form of debt, are very heavy. These are
not just consumer debts. For example, in the USA 75 per cent of
all farmers are in deficit and if the banks had behaved as they
did in 1929-1932, a lot of farmers would have been out of
business. Instead, they have not foreclosed and have allowed
the debts to build up. The final form of debt, and the gravest
for the system, is inter-bank debts. The banks are in debt and
could be forced to close. This is a serious worry for the
capitalist class, and in particular they fear a snowball
effect. To take an example -- and avoiding the obvious case of
Mexico -- there was a group of small Oklahoma stockbrokers who
went bankrupt when there was a rise in the interest rate. Their
collapse also involved some small local banks, again completely
marginal to the national economy, who had engaged in some
speculative oil loans. But within one week these local
bankruptcies had threatened the sixth largest bank in the USA,
which lost $5 billion. People with deposits in the small banks
could not pay their debts, and so it snowballed through the
system. A large bank may have hundreds of billions in deposits,
but their own capital can be as low as a few billion. A loss of
$5 billion could wipe them out and thus cause millions of people
to lose their deposits.
Banking
as a crime
Since the
decline of capitalism, the banking business borders on
criminality. It is a con. The banks take in large short-term
deposits and invest them long-term on the assumption that the
short-term will not be withdrawn. This is not just against the
law but contravenes the elementary basis of banking. If a
number of short-term deposits were withdrawn, then the whole
system tumbles down because the money has been invested where it
is not liquid. There is no bank in the world which can repay
more than one-third of its deposits. If there was panic and
people were to demand their deposits, then the banking system
would not be capable of coping. During the collapse of the
German Herstadt and American Franklin banks in 1974, the world’s
top bankers made a decision in Basle not to allow another major
bank to go under. They agreed that the resources would be
advanced to avoid such a panic which could threaten the world
credit system. They took and applied that decision. During the
present recession no major bank has been permitted to collapse.
Can this
system continue forever? What are the limits of its
application? Does the world capitalist system have the funds to
save major governments, firms and banks? Until now they have
done so. President Reagan intervened to save the Polish
government from being declared bankrupt. Some American banks
were pressing for such a declaration of bankruptcy because the
Polish state was unable to repay some of the interest which was
due. Reagan stepped in for an obvious reason. He knew that a
small default to one small American bank would have spread to
the entire Western banking system -- the Polish government owes
more than $15 billion to private banks in the West. The price
of some Western banks also going bankrupt was too high.
The
missing lender of last resort
Can the
world banking system continue to roll over credits and inflate
the total credit loan? I doubt if this can be done forever --
perhaps for a further limited period. If they continue to do so
they face two major problems. The first pertains to the
distribution of risks, to inter-imperialist rivalry and the
absence of a lender of the last resort. This system can only be
controlled if there is a world bourgeois state with a world
central bank which would function on a world scale in the same
way as each of the national central banks does on a national
scale. That is, it would lend money to the private banks to
avoid their collapse, but private property and competition
prevents the creation of such a world state. Because there is
inter-imperialist rivalry, there can be no lender of last
resort. Thus, there always exists the question of dividing the
risks and subsequent costs. This is open for negotiation and
horse trading. What part will the Americans, Germans, Japanese,
British, French or Italians pay?
As in the
1920s there is no single imperial power which can impose such a
division. After the 1939-1945 war the USA could do that,
likewise prior of the 1914 war the British were in such a
position. Today, the inter-imperialist relationship of forces
is such that the USA cannot impose anything on Japan or Western
Europe; take, for example, the case of the Soviet pipeline.
If the
burden of debt is only a few billion, that can be resolved and
divided up, but what when it is hundreds of billions? The
accumulated debts of the Latin American states is already more
than $100 billion, that of the workers’ states not far short,
and amongst the largest multinationals in excess of $100
billion. In Britain industrial firms owe the banks £40
billion. With no lender of the last resort, the danger exists
that one government will refuse to pay and not help bail out
another country or its banks. As the inter-imperialist
competition increases, so does that danger.
Deflation
The second
difficulty relates to the function of deflationary policies, the
rise in the interest rate and the strangling of fresh credit.
These are social as well as technical policies. They are being
used to weaken the working class via mass unemployment and have
the long-term goal of sapping the strength and militancy of the
labour movement. They also are intended, like the capitalist
crises, to clear dead wood from the system. But that means
bankruptcy, and, as I have argued, that threatens the future of
the banking system itself. The other question is how to
discipline the banks. How do you force them to cease credit
expansion while at the same time avoiding a crisis of 1929-1932
proportions?
That is the
dilemma for the ruling class. Outright deflation entails a
collapse of the banking system while all-out inflation stops the
system functioning. Today, politics are a mix of the two.
The ruling
class is faced with a very serious threat from a monetary and
credit crisis on a world scale. It cannot resolve it easily.
It faces significant social and political resistance from the
working class and the colonial revolution. Within the
imperialist states there is a growing rivalry. There is the
clash with the workers’ states. All in all, in comparison to
the 1930s, the capitalist class has less control. That is why
it is possible to predict that capitalism cannot resolve the
crisis and that the labour movement will have several successive
opportunities to resolve its way, provided there is a growth of
mass militancy and the emergence of a revolutionary
leadership.
|