Several differences between the
analysis of the Soviet Union contained in my ten theses,
traditionally defended by the Fourth International, and the
analysis contained in Ticktin’s paper, are of an essentially
semantic nature. Some examples will show this.
Ticktin tries to reject the
idea that the bureaucracy is a ruling privileged stratum in the
Soviet Union by stating that it is not the case, and has not
been for several decades, that “anyone who has a job in an
office” is automatically a privileged person in the USSR. [1]
He is right. But does it follow from that that the ruling and
privileged group in the USSR is only the “elite of the
bureaucracy”? Everything depends on the definition of
“bureaucracy”. I would agree with Ticktin that a definition
which Trotsky sometimes uses (“anyone who has a job in an
office”) could lend itself to misunderstandings of the type on
which Ticktin bases his argument. I would most strongly deny,
however, that only the top layer (“the elite”) of “office
workers” is materially privileged.
The correct definition of the
bureaucracy, it seems to me, is that of a social layer which
comprises all those who exercise management (leadership)
functions in any sector of Soviet social life: economy, state,
army, science, arts, etc. All these people are materially
privileged. Their number is much larger than that of a small
“elite”. It probably goes into several millions. This group
retains the control and administration of the social surplus
product. It has a monopoly of power at every level of society.
It cuts off the mass of the workers, the producing peasants, and
a large part of the intelligentsia from direct participation in
decision making, at least at power level. It reflects, in
Marxist terms, and in the broad (“macro-social” and not only
“macro-economic”) sense of the word, the division of labour
between production and accumulation. From the point of view of
Marxist conceptualisation it is, therefore, justified to use that
category of bureaucracy as a socially relevant one, much more
than that of “technocracy” (what is Brezhnev a
“technician” in?).
Whatever may be the sectoral
differences of interests which undoubtedly exist in its ranks
(of which Ticktin underlines that between those at the centre
and those administrating plants), there is a common social
interest which binds it together to keep a monopoly of power,
because it is the basis of important privileges (in the field of
consumption).
Ticktin begins by stating that
you can understand the functioning of the Soviet economy neither
in terms of planning nor in terms of the market. He then goes on
to say that its “central dynamic” is “self
contradictory”. “In other words, we find not one central
dynamic but one which is compounded of several conflicting laws
or tendencies reflecting the social groups in society”. [2]
Possibly. But this is just a paraphrase, not a definition in
Marxist terms. Am I mistaken when I say that the
“self-contradictory central dynamic” is exactly the same
thing as the hybrid and self-contradictory combination of the
logic of the plan and the logic of maximum private appropriation
of consumer goods by the rulers of society, which I indicate as
the basic contradiction of the Soviet economy? After all,
Ticktin himself states that “the enterprise salaried
personnel” is “only interested in maximizing their own
personal welfare”. [3]
Ticktin criticises a sentence
of mine which states that “the bureaucracy has no political,
social or economic means at its disposal to make the defence of
its own material interests coincide with the mode of production
from which it draws its privileges”. [4]
He goes on to say that, insofar as the bureaucrats occupy a
certain necessary function in production, they occupy a specific
production relation. If they were to be removed, there would be
either total collapse or another system. [5]
But this is obviously begging the question: Into what
production relation does the Soviet plant manager find himself
inserted? Evidently not only that of “commanding the
workers” (quite incompletely, be it said in passing; one of
the merits of Ticktin’s paper is to have brought this out
clearly). He also finds himself in a specific relation with
other managers: those of the plants or shops which deliver raw
materials and machines, and those of the enterprises which take
over the finished goods produced in the factory which he
manages.
Now it is my contention that this
production relation – to formulate it in a general way: the
specific inter-relationship between different economic units –
can basically take only two forms: the form of the market or the
form of the plan (“a posteriori” adjustment or “a
priori” decision). I, therefore, conclude, in conformity
with everything which Ticktin writes, that the way in which the
bureaucrats operate, in order to maximise their consumption,
disorganises the plan. Ticktin replies that this form of
production relation is not bureaucratically centralised planning
at all. If you replace bureaucratic management by democratic
workers management (“social control”), you will get
“another system”, namely, “real planning” instead of
“bad administration”. The dispute is again evidently
semantic. Likewise one could say that under monopoly capitalism
there are no longer any “real market forces” at work, but
only “monopolistic competition”, which is something “quite
different”. You can then change the basic two-fold subdivision
of the forms of objective socialisation of labour from two, into
four, five, six, etc. At the end of the operation, however, the
annoying question will arise, whether the difference between
“competitive capitalism” and “monopoly capitalism” in
their mutual relation to the market, is not much slighter than
the difference between, say, monopoly capitalism and the Soviet
economy; whether the difference between a “centrally and
wastefully administered economy” and “real socialist
planning”, in their mutual relation to planning, is not
qualitatively smaller than that between a “centrally and
wastefully administered economy” and monopoly capitalism. As
the answer to these questions is obvious, we are back where we
started, i.e. with the recognition that the Soviet economy is a
bureaucratically deformed, degenerate and wasteful variant
of a planned economy ... but a variant nonetheless of a planned
economy and not of a non-existent “third form” of
socialisation of labour, neither spontaneous nor conscious ...
Our main difference with
Ticktin, which is not semantic but substantial, relates to
“the central economic feature of the USSR today” which he
identifies as “waste”. This is a slight exaggeration when it
concerns a country which became mysteriously transformed
(through pure waste of resources?) from an underdeveloped
country into the second industrial power of the world within a
generation. It would be much more correct to say that the
“central economic feature of the USSR” is growth plus waste,
growth in spite of (“growing”) waste, real growth beside
growing waste. This is a rather pungent synthesis of the
“contradictory central dynamic” to be sure. But it
characterises the USSR as something quite different from a
stagnant or retrogressive society which is basically wasteful
and nothing else (e.g. the Roman Empire in its decadence).
Ticktin’s refusal to admit a
contradiction between the logic of central planning and the
material self-interest of the bureaucracy leads to paradoxical
results. He is forced to formulate rhetorical questions which
remain without answers. Why doesn’t the “central
administrative elite” admit workers’ control and social
control over the planning mechanism, if not because it is afraid
of losing its material privileges? Why is there a
conflict between the “planners” and the factory managers, if
not because the logic of the plan (i.e. the fundamental drive to
recognise all labour as immediately social which results from
the suppression of private property and private labour) works
against management practices which are exclusively attuned to
maximising the consumer needs of the managers? Why do
the managers hoard (and waste) raw materials, equipment, etc.,
if not in order to maximise their income? Why would the
introduction of a profit-system as the basis for calculating the
management’s rewards not operate any basic change in this, as
long as planning subsists (i.e. as long as “market forces”
and individual plant managers cannot determine prices, wages,
and investments)? Answering these questions allows one to
understand the basic contradictions of Soviet society much
better than through putting a unilateral emphasis on waste, and
waste alone.
Ticktin correctly states that
the trend towards the strengthening of market forces implies a
trend towards restoration of capitalism. He also correctly
states that this trend cannot break through qualitatively,
without previously disposing of the resistance of the workers
(to the re-introduction of a “free labour market”, i.e.
right of managers to fire workers among other things. Though
this would not be the only aspect of Soviet society which the
workers would defend. We have the feeling that they would
likewise resist the private appropriation of the plants by
foreign or native owners.). This prognosis, which dovetails
nicely with our analysis, leads, however, to a striking gap in
Ticktin’s definition of Soviet society.
When Trotsky states that the
workers in capitalist countries should defend their democratic
freedom against a fascist threat, he phrased this as a defence not
of the bourgeois state but of the “embryonic elements of
proletarian democracy within bourgeois society”. Would Ticktin
say that the absence of a labour market and the existence of the
proletariat’s right to job security in the USSR are just
“embryonic elements of socialised planning” in a
“wastefully administered society”? The dispute would at
first seem semantic. But the absurdity of such a position soon
appears. Permanent job security and the absence of a labour
market are just not side issues or some secondary aspects of the
social system. They are part of the basic relations of
production in the USSR. Together with others, they justify our
definition of that society as still being a society in
transition between capitalism and socialism (which is synonymous
with a workers state), albeit an extremely bureaucratised and
wasteful one, where the removal of the bureaucracy’s monopoly
of power and of bureaucratic mismanagement through a political
revolution, through the establishment of workers democracy and
workers management, would open the road to socialism without
having to undergo the birthpangs of a new social revolution, and
without having to remove a “social system” in favour of a
completely new one.
Notes
1.
All references to H.H. Ticktin: Towards a Political Economy
of the USSR, in: Critique, No.1, Spring
1973 - Here p.38.
2.
op. cit., p.22.
3.
op. cit., p.32.
4.
op. cit., p.34.
5.
op. cit., p.35.
|