The
manifestations of American imperialism began to appear as early
as the nineteenth century, relative to Latin American countries,
and later in the Pacific zone (expansionism toward Japan,
conquest of the Philippines). Since the beginning of World War
I, American imperialism has extended itself on a global scale.
Thus, in the framework of inter-imperialist competition,
American imperialism appears as the great victor of two
imperialist world conflicts. In point of fact, it is the only
victor whose military and economic forces gained from these two
wars. All of the principal competitors were enfeebled by either
one or both of these conflicts.
It
is not necessary to examine in detail the causes of this
superiority of American imperialism over her competitors. The
principal reasons are well known: immense richness in raw
materials; greater equilibrium between industry and agriculture;
broader territorial and demographic bases, which permitted the
enjoyment of important economies of scale in matters of
industrial mass production; the absence of semi-feudal vestiges,
which allowed the expansion of a purer capitalism than that of
the other imperialist countries, etc.
It
must be accentuated, however, that the ascent of American
imperialism toward the position of the first power in the world
represents a dialectical process during which the contradictions
of the rest of the world have had a tendency to breed, even in
the midst of American society. The imperialist American
bourgeoisie cannot engage in this expedition toward world
domination without at the same time assuming the leadership of
the entire capitalist world. In that position they are
confronted by anti-capitalist forces which each day grow more
numerous and powerful. Because of this fact, American
imperialism is often directed in its decisions by the political
imperatives involved in the global defence of the international
capitalist system, a system which at times may enter into
conflict with the particular
historical interests of American imperialism itself. The
Marshall Plan has to be interpreted in this light. Far from
being an enterprise of the pastoralization
of Europe or of its submission to the will of Washington,
historically the Marshall Plan was the initial phase in the
reconstitution of an autonomous
force in Western
European imperialism—that is to say, precisely the re-creation
of a force competitive with that of the United States.
This
decision was not, however, irrational. It simply reflects a
choice between two evils, both of which Washington had to face
following the Second World War: either assist in the collapse of
Western European capitalism, or permit the reappearance of a
powerful competitor. American imperialism chose the lesser evil,
by its lights.
These
prefatory remarks are essential in order to avoid falling into
economism, and to prevent too simple an interpretation of the
economic roots of American imperialism.
I.
Surplus and Export of Capital.
The
principal economic root of American imperialism remains the one
classically defined by Lenin for the whole imperialist era: the
existence, in imperialist countries, of a surplus of capital
which is poured into other parts of the globe in search of
superprofits. The only modification which should be applied to
the Leninist definition is the conclusion that, in the actual
historical context of the period following the Second World War,
this surplus of capital was no longer directed exclusively, nor
even principally, into colonial or semi-colonial (i.e.
underdeveloped) countries, but was spread equally and in
increasing proportions among other industrially developed
imperialist lands.
This
important variant of the Leninist theory can be explained by the
following factors:
1.
The significant difference in technology and the productivity of
labour between American imperialism on the one hand, and that of
the other imperialist powers on the other.
2.
The difference between the military and political power of the
United States and that of the other imperialist powers, a
difference which is even more pronounced than that in the
economic sphere.
3.
The increasing insecurity weighing upon investments in colonial
and semi-colonial countries, in which there is a growing
profusion of revolutionary liberation movements.
4.
The contraction of the geographic area in which surplus capital
may still be invested with profit, a contraction resulting
notably from the overthrow of capitalism in an expanding portion
of the world.[1]
“During
the last quarter of a century the essential direction of the
investment of exported American capital has been into other
imperialist countries.”
The
end result of these diverse tendencies is that the difference
between the rate of profit in the United States and that which
American capital (exploiting advantages of productivity which
consequently assured it significant monopolistic superprofits)
may obtain in other countries is sufficiently large to make
exportation of capital into other imperialist countries
definitely more appealing than investments in under-developed
countries where greater insecurity neutralises the attraction of
an even higher rate of profit.
Certainly,
as American capital gradually discovers outlets in the world,[2]
a process of equal distribution and the levelling off of the
productivity of labour and technological development will
progressively occur between the United States and the other
imperialist countries. Such a process will reduce the difference
in the rate of profit between them, and will
"revalorize" the underdeveloped world as the only area
where important superprofits may be acquired.
In
the same way, an eventual prolongation of détente
between the United States and the Soviet Union will open
possibilities — although very modest ones — of investment of
American capital in countries with a socialist economic base,
similar to that already achieved by Fiat and Renault in the
automotive field.
But
all of the investment possibilities cannot change the
fundamental fact that during the last quarter of a century the
essential direction of the investment of exported American
capital has been into other imperialist countries, rather than
to the rest of the world.
It
must be remembered that this export of capital admirably suits
an economic necessity inherent in the capitalistic system of
monopolies. It represents a response to a double menace: the
decline in the average rate of profit experienced in the
principal imperialist citadel, and the massive accumulation of
capital which cannot be invested in that citadel without
endangering the average rate of profit with a new, serious
decline.
II.
The growing role of the war and armaments economy in the United
States.
The
accumulation of a growing surplus of capital which can no longer
be profitably invested in the normal sectors of the economy not
only encourages its export but also increases research in new
fields of investment where capital will yield an average profit
from the monopolised sectors of the economy without threatening
the rate of profit from the entire system of monopolistic
capital. The production of armaments (and its extension into
space production) constitutes a similar "substitutive field
of unparalleled investment" (to use Rosa Luxembourg's
phrase).
The
advantages of the realisation of monopolistic capital in the
area of armaments are obvious. It does not reduce the scope of
capital already invested in the rest of industry. On the
contrary, it markedly stimulated the production of heavy
industry and certain specific raw materials. It does not become
a substitute for other products normally produced. On the
contrary, it creates merchandise whose sole purchaser is the
State, and whose only value, in terms of consumption, is the
strengthening of American imperialism internationally.
“In
a world divided into two profoundly antagonistic camps, genuine
disarmament is Utopian.”
It
creates, in addition, other, by no means negligible, marginal
benefits. It permits the reduction of conjectural fluctuations
by stabilising a considerable volume of investment. Thus it
protects the American economy against a return of a catastrophic
crisis similar to that of 1929 (without the power, however, to
prevent the appearance of periodic recessions which are not,
finally, any less grave than the average crises which capitalism
has known throughout its history). It brings an automatic
guarantee of profit to monopolies in a growing number of sectors
(all those related to national defence).
The
increasing importance of arms production in the American economy
is indicated above all by the preponderance it acquires in
expanding sectors, such as electronics, aircraft, and chemistry.
It results in a double symbiosis which stimulates the
imperialist expansion of American capital by producing a double
self perpetuation.
1.
The symbiosis of certain areas of the monopolies, and of the
production of armaments in these areas, developing a
"vested interest" in the maintenance and expansion of
arms production.
2.
The symbiosis of certain positions of authority in the armed
forces and in the machinery of State, which gives these
positions a "vested interest" in the maintenance and
expansion of the military budget at an astronomical level.
This
double symbiosis is all the more dangerous since it tends to
reproduce itself in foreign countries, following the
establishment of American bases abroad, the military missions in
foreign countries and the military "aid" to
"friendly" governments menaced by "internal
subversion" or by "external Communist
aggression."
Even
former President Eisenhower, as conservative as he was at the
end of his Presidency, publicly expressed his fears about the
formidable growth of the industrial-military-political
establishment. That establishment lives on and prospers
essentially from the continual increase in arms expenditures,
and it requires international conflicts in order to justify this
expansion to the American taxpayer.
Nevertheless,
it would be foolish to consider the important role the
production of armaments plays in the heart of the American
economy as simply the result of maneuvers by this particular
Mafia in the centre of the large American bourgeoisie. The
entire bourgeoisie is condemned to practice the politics of
permanent rearmament, confronted as it is with a permanent
revolution on a world wide scale and with the industrial and
military growth of countries which have already overthrown
capitalism. The goal of every one of the disarmament conferences
is not actual disarmament, but the attempt to rationalise the course of armament, to render it supportable by
the budgets of the U.S.A. and the U.S.S.R. which are not, after
all, unlimited.
In
a world divided into two profoundly antagonistic camps, genuine
disarmament is Utopian. Still more Utopian is the idea that
monopoly capitalism could reorient the sixty or seventy billion
dollars it annually spends on arms production to fields of
public service, education, health, and aid to underdeveloped
countries. Such a redirection would first of all require the
conversion of the bourgeoisie, the very class devoted to profit
motives, into a class working for the good of the human species.
Any diffusion of masses of capital outside the areas of
disarmament would rapidly menace the investment of
"civil" capital and the rate of profit. It will never
happen.
III.
Supply of strategic raw materials.
Unlike
most of its competitors, American imperialism was characterised
by the fact that it found within its own borders the essential
raw materials for modern industry. Even in the period
immediately following World War I, the importation of raw
materials remained fundamentally secondary — rubber, silk,
sugar or tin, products easily replaced by synthetics.
However,
the formidable expansion of American industrial production at
the end of World War II changed the situation. Today the U.S.A.
must import increasing quantities of raw materials as essential
as petroleum, iron ore, bauxite, copper, manganese, and nickel.
Moreover America s own resources in these areas are rapidly
diminishing and, in the case of petroleum, could be exhausted by
the end of the century. America depends entirely upon imports
for chromium, cobalt, and columbarium, indispensable to iron
production.
In other
words, three-quarters of a century behind its principal
competitors, the U.S.A. must now launch a drive for new sources
of raw materials in the world; for petroleum, in Latin America,
the Middle East, and Nigeria; for iron ore, in Latin America and
West Africa; for other minerals, in Canada, Australia, and
Africa, etc. In this search it will collide not only with
liberation movements in various colonial and semi-colonial
countries, but with the competition of other imperialist nations
like Great Britain, Japan, France, West Germany, indeed, even
Spain.
Often
the appropriation and possession of these sources of raw
materials involves political conflict, coups
d'etat and local war (notably in West Africa in the last few
years). It may involve the establishment of missions, perhaps
American military bases. The need for new sources explains the
tenacity with which American imperialism clings to countries
like Venezuela and Brazil for they have become precisely the
sources of supply of raw materials indispensable for Big
Business in the United States.[3]
“In
the end, American imperialism will not achieve world
domination.”
IV.
Inter-imperialist competition in the heart of the Third
World.
Although
the export of American capital into underdeveloped countries has
been of less volume than the same export into other imperialist
countries, nonetheless it has not been negligible. When it
concerns important countries, like Indonesia or Brazil, or
countries of enormous, scarcely tapped potential, like the
Congo, the export of American capital results in growing
interference by American imperialism in the internal affairs of
these semi-colonial countries. Conflicts develop with other
imperialist powers, particularly the former colonial powers
which American imperialism is gradually replacing.
In
the last twenty years, the most typical examples of the way in
which American capital has taken over from former colonial
capital are its domination of Indonesia (replacing Dutch
capital), Morocco (replacing French capital), and Iran (English
capital). Without a doubt, in the Congo we are witnessing the début
of a similar replacement of capital, in this case Belgian,
although at this moment it is reflected less in capital
investments than in the reorientation of foreign trade.
All
this imperialist substitution was not achieved simply by
maneuvering behind the scenes. It produced acute national and
international conflicts, often accompanied by bloodbaths. From
the overthrow of Mossadegh to the assassination of Ben Barka and
the ascent to power of Mobutu by a coup d'etat, the course of this substitution was marked by murder,
conspiracy, and oppressive operations whose victims number in
the hundreds of thousands.
In
the end, American imperialism will not achieve world domination.
The dream of an "American Century" lasted, in fact,
only five years, from 1945 to 1950. The dream was destroyed not
only by the strengthening of anti-capitalist forces on a world
scale, but by the law of unequal development which functions
inexorably in the heart of the imperialist world and does not
permit any acquired position to last forever. In comparison with
the 1945-1950 period, the principal competitors of American
imperialism (with the exception of Great Britain) have
strengthened, not weakened, their positions relative to American
imperialism. The inter-imperialist competition is more acute
than before. There will be no super-imperialism, but rather a
continual struggle of imperialist forces to shift the revenue of
power in their favour.
However,
the battle of inter-imperialist competition is taking place in a
new global context: the loss to Capital of a third of the world;
the constant extension of new revolutionary forces and movements
that threaten to wrest new countries away from Capital. In these
conditions, inter-imperialist competition will dissolve into
inter-imperialist solidarity before the vital threats which
weigh on the total system. Stalin's hope of seeing the outbreak
of new inter-imperialist wars turns out to be in vain (assuming
one disregards local conflicts between various pawns of
imperialism in Africa, Cyprus, and elsewhere).
V.
The defence of general conditions in the realisation of capital.
One
of the economic motives appropriate to American imperialism is
that of defending the conditions of realisation of invested
American capital when those conditions seem to be deteriorating,
or when they are exposed to threat. It is precisely in this
sense that the coup d'etat
in Guatemala, in defence of the investments of United Fruit,
must be understood; or the military mission to Venezuela
defending the investments of Creole Petroleum; or the
intervention of the CIA in the military coup d'etat in Brazil in defence of United States Steel Corporation
investments. The same intervention in the military coup d'etat in Greece permitted America's Litton Industries to make
huge investments of capital under exceptionally favourable
conditions.
However,
it would be false to see this imperialist intervention in too
restricted a way, that is as merely the defence of capital
already invested. Additionally, imperialist intervention is a
question of preserving future opportunities and avoiding the
danger of a chain reaction which would menace strong positions
in one country by events in another.
For example,
direct investments of American capital in South Vietnam are very
modest. But there are more important investments in Thailand,
and considerably more important ones in Malaysia, in Indonesia
and India. By intervening with a counterrevolutionary war of
aggression in the civil war in Vietnam, American imperialism
covers capitalist positions in all the neighbouring countries
and attempts to preserve its future opportunities in the eastern
part of the Asian continent. Today, the imperialist strategy is
unavoidably a global one. Necessarily, the defence of capital
does not take place where that capital is invested but occurs in
other countries the collapse of whose advance positions would
constitute a grave threat to those, properly called, strong
areas.
That
is why an analysis of the global, economic moving forces of
American imperialism can come to only one conclusion: to be
effective, anti-capitalist forces must oppose the international
counterrevolutionary strategy of Big Capital with a
corresponding world-wide, global strategy.
ERNEST
MANDEL, one of the world's foremost Marxist thinkers, has
been banned from lecturing in the United States by the State
Department. His work is widely published in Europe and in the
United States, where his essays appear frequently in the New
Left Review. Ernest Mandel lives in Brussels.
DANIEL
DODSON is Professor of
English and Comparative Literature at Columbia University. He is
author of the novel The Man Who Ran Away and a recently
published book on Malcolm Lowry. His criticism and fiction have
been published in the United States and abroad. Dodson lives
with his family in Sparkhill, New York, in the middle of the
woods.
[1]
. An investigation by a firm of management consultants in
Chicago in 1960 revealed that thirty-five large American trusts
had a net rate of profit (corporate profits after taxes) of 9.2
% in the U.S.A. and 14.2 % abroad. (U.S. NEWS AND WORLD REPORT,
Jan. 1, 1962, and NEWSWEEK, March 8, 1965, arrived at analogous
conclusions.)
[2]
Direct foreign investment by American corporations went from 7.2
billion dollars in 1946 to 40.6 billion in 1963 and 54.5 billion
in 1966.
[3]
According to Harry Magdoff, American imports of certain raw
materials evolved in the following manner in terms of percent of
their production in the United States.
|
1937-1939 |
1966 |
Iron
Ore |
3
% |
43
% |
Copper |
-13
% |
18
% |
Lead |
0
% |
131
% |
Zinc |
7
% |
140
% |
Bauxite |
113
% |
638
% |
Petroleum |
-
4 % |
31
% |
|