In the history of class
society, the situation of each social class is a unique
combination of stability and change. The structure remains the
same; conjunctural features are often profoundly modified.
There is a tremendous
difference both in standard of living and in social environment
between the slave on the patriarchal Greek farms of the sixth
century BC, the slave on Sicilian plantations in the first
century BC, and a clerical or handicraft slave in Rome or the
south of France in the fourth century AD Nonetheless all three
of these were slaves, and the identity of their social status is
undeniable. A nobleman living at the court of Louis XV did not
have very much in common with a lord of the manor in Normandy or
Burgundy seven centuries earlier – except that both lived on
surplus labor extracted from the peasantry through feudal or
semi-feudal institutions.
When we look at the history of
the modern proletariat, whose direct ancestors were the
unattached and uprooted wage earners in the medieval towns and
the vagabonds of the 16th century – so strikingly described by
that great novel from my country Till Eulenspiegel – we notice
the same combination of structural stability and conjunctural
change. The proletarian condition is, in a nutshell, the lack of
access to means of production or means of subsistence which, in
a society of generalised commodity production, forces the
proletarian to sell his labor-power. In exchange for this
labor-power he receives a wage which then enables him to acquire
the means of consumption necessary for satisfying his own needs
and those of his family.
This is the structural
definition of the wage earner, the proletarian. From it
necessarily flows a certain relationship to his work, to the
products of his work, and to his overall situation in society,
which can be summarised by the catchword “alienation.” But
there does not follow from this structural definition any
necessary conclusions as to the level of his consumption, the
price he receives for his labor-power, the extent of his needs
or the degree to which he can satisfy them. The only basic
interrelationship between structural stability of status and
conjunctural fluctuations of income and consumption is a very
simple one: Does the wage, whether high or low, whether in
miserable Calcutta slums or in the much publicised comfortable
suburbs of the American megalopolis, enable the proletarian to
free himself from the social and economic obligation to sell his
labor-power? Does it enable him to go into business on his own
account?
Occupational statistics testify
that this is no more open to him today than a hundred years ago.
Nay, they confirm that the part of the active population in
today’s United States which is forced to sell its labor-power
is much higher than it was in Britain when Karl Marx wrote Das
Kapital, not to speak of the United States on the eve
of the American Civil War.
Nobody will deny that the
picture of the working class under neo-capitalism would be
highly oversimplified if it were limited to featuring only this
basic structural stability of the proletarian condition. In
general, though, Marxists who continue to stress the basic
revolutionary role of today’s proletariat in Western
imperialist society avoid that pitfall. It is rather their
critics who are in error, who commit the opposite error in fact
of concentrating exclusively on conjunctural changes in the
situation of the working class, thereby forgetting those
fundamental structural elements which have not changed.
I do not care very much for the
term “neo-capitalism” which is ambiguous, to say the least.
When one speaks about the “neo-reformism” of the Communist
parties in the West, one means, of course, that they are
basically reformist; but when the term “neo-socialists” was
used in the thirties and early forties to define such dubious
figures as Marcel Deat or Henri de Man, one meant rather that
they had stopped being socialists. Some European politicians and
sociologists speak about “neo-capitalism” in the sense that
society has shed some of the basic characteristics of
capitalism. I deny this most categorically, and therefore attach
to the term “neo-capitalism” the opposite connotation: a
society which has all the basic elements of classical
capitalism.
Nevertheless I am quite
convinced that starting either with the great depression of
1929-32 or with the second world war, capitalism entered into a
third stage in its development, which is as different from
monopoly capitalism or imperialism described by Lenin,
Hilferding and others as monopoly capitalism was different from
classical 19th century laissez-faire capitalism. We have to give
this child a name; all other names proposed seem even less
acceptable than “neo-capitalism.” “State monopoly
capitalism,” the term used in the Soviet Union and the
“official” Communist parties, is very misleading because it
implies a degree of independence of the state which, to my mind,
does not at all correspond to present-day reality. On the
contrary, I would say that today the state is a much more direct
instrument for guaranteeing monopoly surplus profits to the
strongest private monopolies than it ever was in the past. The
German term Spätkapitalismus seems interesting, but
simply indicates a time sequence and is difficult to translate
into several languages. So until somebody comes up with a better
name – and this is a challenge to you, friends! – we will
stick for the time being to “neo-capitalism.”
We shall define neo-capitalism
as this latest stage in the development of monopoly capitalism
in which a combination of factors – accelerated technological
innovation, permanent war economy, expanding colonial revolution
– have transferred the main source of monopoly surplus profits
from the colonial countries to the imperialist countries
themselves and made the giant corporations both more independent
and more vulnerable.
More independent, because the
enormous accumulation of monopoly surplus profits enables these
corporations, through the mechanisms of price investment and
self-financing, and with the help of a constant build-up of
sales costs, distribution costs and research and development
expenses, to free themselves from that strict control by banks
and finance capital which characterised the trusts and
monopolies of Hilferding’s and Lenin’s epoch. More
vulnerable, because of shortening of the life cycle of fixed
capital, the growing phenomenon of surplus capacity, the
relative decline of customers in non-capitalist milieus and,
last but not least, the growing challenge of the non-capitalist
forces in the world (the so-called socialist countries, the
colonial revolution and, potentially at least, the working class
in the metropolis) has implanted even in minor fluctuations and
crises the seeds of dangerous explosions and total collapse.
For these reasons,
neo-capitalism is compelled to embark upon all those well-known
techniques of economic programming, of deficit financing and
pump-priming, of incomes policies and wage freezing, of state
subsidising of big business and state guaranteeing of monopoly
surplus profit, which have become permanent features of most
Western economies over the last 20 years. What has emerged is a
society which appears both as more prosperous and more explosive
than the situation of imperialist countries 30 years ago.
It is a society in which the
basic contradictions of capitalism have not been overcome, in
which some of them reach unheard-of dimensions, in which
powerful long-term forces are at work to blow up the system. I
will mention here in passing only some of these forces: The
growing crisis of the international monetary system; the trend
towards a generalised economic recession in the whole capitalist
world; the trend to restrict or suppress the basic democratic
freedoms of the working class, in the first place, free play of
wage bargaining; the trend toward deep and growing
dissatisfaction of producers and consumers with a system which
forces them to lose more and more time producing and consuming
more and more commodities which give less and less satisfaction
and stifle more and more basic human needs, emotions and
aspirations; the contradictions between the accumulation of
wasteful “wealth” in the West and the hunger and misery of
the colonial peoples; the contradictions between the immense
creative and productive potentialities of science and automation
and the destructive horror of nuclear war in the shadow of which
we are forced to live permanently – these epitomise the basic
contradictions of today’s capitalism.
The question has been posed:
Hasn’t the role of the working class been fundamentally
changed in this changed environment? Hasn’t the long-term high
level of employment and the rising real wage undercut any
revolutionary potential of the working class? Isn’t it
changing in composition, and more and more divorced from the
productive process, as a result of growing automation? Don’t
its relations with other social layers, such as white-collar
workers, technicians, intellectuals, students, undergo basic
modifications?
Affirmative answers to these
questions lead to political conclusions of far-reaching
consequence. For some, the stability of the capitalist system in
the West cannot be shaken any more, a theory which is nicely
fitted to nourish a more material interest and psychological
urge of adaptation to that system. For others, that stability
could be shaken only from outside: first of all, from the
non-industrialised regions of the world – the so-called
villages, to repeat Lin Piao’s formula – which will have to
be revolutionised before revolts could again be envisaged in the
imperialist countries themselves (Lin Piao’s cities). Others,
while not questioning the basic instability of neo-capitalism,
see no positive outcome at all because they believe that the
system is able to drug and paralyse its victims. Finally, there
are those who believe that neo-capitalism raises its
gravediggers from within its bosom but see these gravediggers
coming from the groups of outcasts: national and racial
minorities, superexploited sections of the population,
revolutionary students, the new youth vanguard. All these
conclusions share in common the elimination of the proletariat
of metropolitan countries from the central role in the worldwide
struggle against imperialism and capitalism.
It would be easy to limit
oneself to stating an obvious fact: All these theories spring
from a premature rationalisation of a given situation, the fact
that the Western proletariat has receded into the background of
the world revolutionary struggle for the past 20 years, between
1948 and 1968. Now that the French May 1968 revolution has shown
this phenomenon and period to be a temporary one, we should
rather put at the top of the agenda a discussion of
revolutionary perspectives in the West from now on.
Such an answer, valid though it
may be, would remain insufficient and incomplete. For some of
the theories we have just mentioned, while being obvious
rationalisations of the fait accompli, have enough
sophistication and candor not to limit themselves to description
pure and simple. They try to draw conclusions about the
declining revolutionary role of the proletariat in the West from
changes introduced into the very fabric of neo-capitalist
society by technological, economic, social and cultural
transformations of historic proportions and importance. So we
have to meet these arguments on their own ground, and critically
re-examine the dynamics of working class struggles,
consciousness and revolutionary potential against the background
of the changes which neo-capitalism has effected in the
classical modus operandi of the capitalist system.
Our starting point must be the
same as that adopted not only by Karl Marx but also by the
classical school of political economy: the study of the place
human labor occupies in the economic life of contemporary
monopoly capitalism. Three basic facts immediately demand our
attention in that respect.
First, contemporary production
and distribution of material wealth is more than ever based upon
modern industry and the factory. Indeed, one could say that the
third industrial revolution at one and the same time both
reduces industrial labor in the factory as a result of growing
automation and increases industrial labor on a vast scale in
agriculture, distribution, the service industries and
administration. For the automation revolution must be seen as a
vast movement of industrialisation of these different sectors of
economic activity, both economically and socially. We shall have
to draw important conclusions from this trend. But what stands
out is the fact that industrial labor in the broadest sense of
the word – men forced to sell their labor-power to the
manufacturing, cotton-growing, data-processing or
dream-producing factory! – more than ever occupies the central
place in the economy’s structure.
Second, whatever the increase
in consumption of the working class may have been,
neo-capitalism hasn’t modified in any sense whatsoever the
basic nature of work in a capitalist society as alienated labor.
One could even say that in the same way as automation extends
the industrialisation process into every single corner of
economic life, it likewise universalises alienation to an extent
Marx and Engels could only have dimly imagined a hundred years
ago. Many passages on alienation in the Economic-Philosophical
Manuscripts, in The German Ideology
and in the Grundrisse have only been truly
realised in the last decades. And one could make the point that
Marx’s economic analysis of “pure capitalism” is much more
a presentiment of what was going to happen during the 20th
century than a description of what was happening under his eyes
in the 19th century.
In any case, labor under
neo-capitalism is more than ever alienated labor, forced labor,
labor under command of a hierarchy which dictates to the worker
what he has to produce and how he has to produce it. And this
same hierarchy imposes upon him what to consume and when to
consume it, what to think and when to think it, what to dream
and when to dream it, giving alienation new and dreadful
dimensions. It tries to alienate the worker even from his
consciousness of being alienated, of being exploited.
Third, living labor remains
more than ever the sole source of surplus value, the only source
of profit, which is what makes the system tick. One can easily
reveal the striking contradiction of a productive process
heavily pregnant with unlimited potentials of making use-values
abundant, but incapable of functioning smoothly and developing
steadily because these use-values must first of all slip into
the clothes of exchange-values, be sold and meet “effective
demand” before they can be consumed. One can note the
absurdity of a system in which science, technological progress,
humanity’s huge accumulated wealth of equipment, are the main
basis for material production, but in which the “miserly
appropriation of surplus labor” to use Marx’s Grundrisse
phrase, continues to be the only goal of economic growth:
“Profit is our business, and business after all only means
profit.”
But all these contradictions
and absurdities are real, living contradictions and absurdities
of capitalism. These would attain their absolute limit in
universal and total automation which, however, lies completely
beyond its reach because living labor is indispensable for the
further accumulation of capital. One has only to observe how the
billion-dollar corporations haggle and shout like fishwives over
a 50-cent wage increase here and two hours off the workweek
there to see that, whatever ideologues and sociologists might
argue, the hard facts of life confirm what Marx taught us:
Capital’s unlimited appetite for profit is an unlimited
appetite for human surplus labor, for hours and minutes of
unpaid labor. The shorter the workweek becomes, the higher the
actual productivity of labor, the closer and more strictly do
capitalists calculate surplus labor and haggle ever more
furiously over seconds and fractions of seconds, as in time and
motion studies.
Now precisely these three
characteristics of modern labor – its key role in the
productive process, its basic alienation, its economic
exploitation – are the objective roots of its potential role
as the main force to overthrow capitalism, the objective roots
of its indicated revolutionary mission. Any attempt to transfer
that role to other social layers who are unable to paralyse
production at a stroke, who do not play a key role in the
productive process, who are not the main source of profit and
capital accumulation, takes us a decisive step backwards from
scientific to utopian socialism, from socialism which grows out
of the inner contradictions of capitalism to that immature view
of socialism which was to be born from the moral indignation of
men regardless of their place in social production.
Here we have to meet an
objection often voiced both by so-called dogmatic Marxists and
by avowed revisionists or opponents of Marxist theory. Haven’t
we given too general a definition of the working class under
neo-capitalism? Shouldn’t we restrict this category to the
same group which came under this definition in the classical
period of the socialist labor movement, to wit the manual
workers actually engaged in production? Isn’t it true that
this category tends to decline, first relatively and then even
in absolute figures, in the most advanced industrial countries
of the West? Are not the mass of wage and salary earners to
which we have constantly referred too vague and heterogeneous a
grouping to be considered a social class in the Marxist sense of
the word? And isn’t the fading of the revolutionary potential
of the working class in the Western metropolitan countries
causally linked to this diminution of the manual production
workers in the gainfully employed population?
The debate which inevitably
arises from an answer to these questions could easily degenerate
into a semantic squabble if the qualitative, structural nature
of the proletariat is forgotten. Authors like Serge Mallet have
correctly argued that the very nature of the productive process,
under conditions of semi-automation or automation, tends to
incorporate whole new layers into the working class. We do not
accept Mallet’s political conclusions, which have not at all
been confirmed by the May revolt in France. In the forefront of
that revolt we did not find only the “new” working class of
highly skilled workers and technicians in semi-automated
factories like those of the CSF [General Electric] factory in
Brest. Equally present were the classical conveyor-belt workers
of Renault and Sud-Aviation and even the workers of some
declining industrial branches like the shipyard workers of
Nantes and Saint-Nazaire. The categories of the “old’ and
“new” working class created by Mallet do not correspond to
the realities of the process.
But what is valid is the fact
that the distinctions between the “purely” productive manual
production worker, the “purely’ unproductive clerical
white-collar worker, and the “semi-productive” repairman
become more and more effaced as a result of technological change
and innovation itself, and that the productive process of today
tends more and more to integrate manual and non-manual workers,
conveyor-belt semi-skilled and data-processing semi-skilled,
highly skilled repair and maintenance squads and highly skilled
electronics experts. Both in the laboratories and research
departments, before “actual” production starts, and in the
dispatching and inventory departments, when “actual”
production is over, productive labor is created if one accepts
the definition of such labor given in Marx’s Capital.
For all this labor is indispensable for final consumption and is
not simply waste induced by the special social structure of the
economy (as for instance sales costs).
We can return to a point made
before and state that just as the third industrial revolution,
just as automation, tends to industrialise agriculture,
distribution, the service industries and administration, just as
it tends to universalise industry, so it tends to integrate a
constantly growing part of the mass of wage and salary earners
into an increasingly homogeneous proletariat.
This conclusion needs further
elucidation. What are the indicators of the enhanced proletarian
character of these “new” layers of workers which become
progressively integrated into the working class? We could cite
offhand a series of striking facts: reduced wage differentials
between white-collar and manual workers, which is a universal
trend in the West; increased unionisation and union militancy of
these “new” layers, which is equally universal (in Brussels
as in New York, schoolteachers, electricians, telephone and
telegraph workers have been among the militant trade unionists
in the last five years); rising similarities of consumption, of
social status and environment of these layers; growing
similarity of working conditions, i.e., growing similarity of
monotonous, mechanised, uncreative, nerve-racking and
stultifying work in factory, bank, bus, public administration,
department stores and airplanes.
If we examine the long-term
trend, there is no doubt that the basic process is one of
growing homogeneity and not of growing heterogeneity of the
proletariat. The difference in income, consumption and status
between an unskilled laborer and a bank clerk or highschool
teacher is today incommensurably smaller than it was fifty or a
hundred years ago.
But there is an additional and
striking feature of this process of integration of new layers
into the working class under neo-capitalism: That is the
equalisation of the conditions of reproduction of labor-power,
especially of skilled and semiskilled labor-power. In the days
of 19th century capitalism, there was elementary education for
the manual worker, lower-middle-school education for the
white-collar worker, highschool education for the technician;
the reproduction of agricultural labor-power often didn’t need
any education whatsoever. Universities were strictly
institutions for the capitalist class.
The very technological
transformation, of which neo-capitalism is both a result and a
motive force, has completely modified the levels of education.
Today, outside of completely unskilled laborers for whom there
are very few jobs any more in industry, strictly speaking, and
for whom tomorrow there might be no jobs available in the whole
economy, conditions of reproduction of skill for industrial
workers, technicians, white-collar employees, service workers
and clerks are completely identical in generalised highschool
education. In fact, in several countries, radicals are fighting
for compulsory education up to 18 years in a single type of
school, with growing success.
Uniform conditions of
reproduction of labor-power entail at one and the same time a
growing homogeneity of wages and salaries (value and price of
labor-power), and a growing homogeneity of labor itself. In
other words, the third industrial revolution is repeating in the
whole society what the first industrial revolution achieved
inside the factory system: a growing indifference towards the
particular skill of labor, the emergence of generalised human
labor, transferable from one factory to another, as a concrete
social category (corresponding historically to the abstract
general human labor which classical political economy found as
the only source of exchange-value.)
Let it be said in passing that
it would be hard to understand the dimensions and importance of
the universal student revolt in the imperialist countries
without taking into account the tendencies which we have
sketched here: growing integration of intellectual labor into
the productive process; growing standardisation, uniformity and
mechanisation of intellectual labor; growing transformation of
university graduates from independent professionals and
capitalist entrepreneurs into salary earners appearing in a
specialised labor market – the market for skilled intellectual
labor where supply and demand make salaries fluctuate as they
did on the manual labor market before unionisation but fluctuate
around an axis which is the reproduction cost of skilled
intellectual labor. What do these trends mean but the growing
proletarianisation of intellectual labor, its tendency to become
part and parcel of the working class?
Of course students are not yet
workers. But it would be as wrong to define them by their social
origin as it would be to define them by their social future.
They are a social layer in transition. Contemporary universities
are a huge melting pot into which flow youth of different social
classes, to become for a certain time a new homogeneous social
layer. Out of this interim layer there arises on the one hand an
important part of the future capitalist class and its main
agents among the higher middle classes, and on the other hand a
growing proportion of the future working class.
But since the second category
is numerically much more important than the first; and since the
student milieu (precisely because of its transitional severance
of basic bonds with a specific social class and because of its
specific access to knowledge not yet excessively specialised)
can gain a much sharper and much quicker consciousness than the
individual worker of the basic ills of capitalist society; and
since intellectual labor is increasingly a victim of the same
basic alienation which characterises all labor under capitalism,
the student revolt can become a real vanguard revolt of the
working class as a whole, triggering a powerful revolutionary
upsurge as it did this May in France.
Let us restate the first
conclusion we have arrived at. Neo-capitalism in the long run
strengthens the working class much as did laissez-faire
capitalism or monopoly capitalism in its first stage.
Historically, it makes the working class grow both numerically
and in respect to its vital role in the economy. It thereby
strengthens the latent power of the working class and underlines
its potential capacity to overthrow capitalism and to
reconstruct society on the basis of its own socialist ideal.
Immediately new questions
arise. If this be so, will not the increased stability of the
neo-capitalist system, its wide use of neo-Keynesian and
macroeconomic techniques, its avoidance of catastrophic economic
depressions of the 1929-33 type, its capacity to shape the
workers’ consciousness through manipulation and the use of
mass media, permanently repress these revolutionary
potentialities? These questions boil down to two basic arguments
which we shall deal with successively. One is the system’s
capacity to reduce economic fluctuations and contradictions
sufficiently to assure enough reforms to guarantee a gradual
easing of social tensions between capital and labor. The other
is the system’s capacity of integrating and engulfing the
industrial proletariat as consumers and ideologically
conditioned members of the society, to quote Baran and
Sweezy’s Monopoly Capital.
On the economic plane, we can
briefly sketch the trends which make long-term “stability in
growth” impossible for neo-capitalism. When the growth rate
increases, as it did in Western Europe for 15 years from 1950 to
1965, then conditions of near-full employment enable the workers
to rapidly increase real wages which, together with the rapidly
increasing organic composition of capital, tend to push down the
rate of profit. The system must react, and its reactions usually
take two forms, or a combination of both. One is
rationalisation, automation, that is, increased competition
between men and machines through reconstitution of the reserve
army of labor to keep down the rate of increase of real wages.
The other is voluntary or compulsory wage restraints, income
policies, anti-strike and anti-union legislation, that is,
attempts to prevent labor from utilising relatively favorable
conditions in the labor market in order to increase its share of
the new value it creates.
Increased growth rates under
neo-capitalist conditions of “administered prices,”
“investment through prices,” state-guaranteed monopoly
surplus profits and a permanent arms economy, also mean
inflation.
Every attempt to stop inflation
strangles the boom and precipitates a recession. Investment
fluctuations and monetary disorders combine to increase economic
instability, further abetted by stepped-up capital concentration
both nationally and internationally, so that the system tends
towards a marginal increase in unemployment and a generalised
recession in the whole Western world. Both trends push down the
rate of growth, as does the system’s inability to constantly
increase the rate of growth of armaments, that is, their share
of the gross national product, without endangering enlarged
reproduction, consequently economic growth itself. The
accumulation of huge masses of surplus capital and of increasing
surplus capacity in the capitalist world industry acts in the
same sense of dampening the long-term rate of growth.
What emerges in the end is less
the picture of a new type of capitalism successfully reducing
overproduction than the picture of a temporary delay in the
appearance of overproduction – “zurückstauen,”
as one says in German – by means of huge debt stockpiling and
monetary inflation, which lead towards the crisis and collapse
of the world monetary system.
Are these basic economic trends
compatible with a secular decrease in social tensions between
capital and labor? There is very little reason to believe this.
Granted that the phases of rapid economic growth – more rapid
in the last 20 years than in any comparable past period in the
history of capitalism – create the material possibilities for
increasing real wages and expanding mass consumption. But the
attempts to base pessimistic predictions about the revolutionary
potential of the working class on this trend of rising real
wages overlooks the dual effect of the economic booms under
capitalism on the working class.
On the one hand, a combination
of near-full employment and a rapid rise of productive forces,
especially under conditions of rapid technological change,
likewise leads to an increase in the needs of the working class.
That portion of the value of labor-power which Marx calls
historically determined and is attributable to the given level
of culture tends to increase most rapidly under such conditions,
generally much more rapidly than wages. Paradoxically, it is
precisely when wages rise that the gap between the value and the
price of labor-power tends to grow, that the socially determined
needs of the working class grow more rapidly than its purchasing
power. The debate of the past decade in the United States and
other imperialist countries on the growing gap between
individual consumption and unsatisfied needs of social
consumption, publicised by Galbraith as the contrast between
private affluence and public squalor, illustrates this point.
Furthermore, rising real wages
are constantly threatened by erosion. They are threatened by
inflation. They are threatened by structural unemployment
generated through technological change and automation. They are
threatened by wage restraint and wage-freeze policies. They are
threatened by recessions. The more the workers are accustomed to
relatively high wages, the more they react against even marginal
reductions in their accustomed level of consumption, the more
all the just-named threats are potential starting points of real
social explosion.
It is no accident that the
working class youth is quicker to react and move to the
forefront of these revolts. The older generations of workers
tend to compare their miseries in the depression and during the
war with the conditions of the last 15 years and can even view
them as a state of bliss. Younger workers don’t make these
comparisons. They take for granted what the system has
established as a social minimum standard of living, without
being at all satisfied, either by the quantity or quality of
what they get, and react sharply against any deterioration of
conditions. That’s why they have been in the front ranks of
very militant strikes over the last two years in countries as
widely different as Italy, West Germany, Britain and France.
That’s why they played a key role in the May revolution in
France.
Even more important than the
basic instability and insecurity of the proletarian condition
which neo-capitalism hasn’t overcome and cannot overcome is
the inherent trend under neo-capitalism to push the class
struggle to a higher plane. As long as the workers were hungry
and their most immediate needs were unattended to, wage
increases inevitably stood in the center of working class
aspirations. As long as they were threatened by mass
unemployment, reductions in the work-week were essentially seen
as means of reducing the dangers of redundancy. But when
employment is relatively high and wages are constantly rising,
attention becomes gradually transferred to more basic aspects of
capitalist exploitation.
The “wage drift”
notwithstanding, industry-wide wage bargaining and attempts of
neo-capitalist governments to impose incomes policies tend to
focus attention more on the division of national income, on the
great aggregates of wages, profits and taxes, than on the
division of the newly created value at the factory level.
Permanent inflation, constant debates around government fiscal
and economic policies, sudden disturbances of the labor market
through technological innovation and relocation of whole
industries, draw the workers’ attention in the same direction.
Classical capitalism educated
the worker to struggle for higher wages and shorter working
hours in his factory. Neo-capitalism educates the worker to
challenge the division of national income and orientation of
investment at the superior level of the economy as a whole.
Growing dissatisfaction with
labor organisation in the plant stimulates this very tendency.
The higher the level of skill and education of the working class
– and the third industrial revolution leaves no room for an
uneducated and unskilled working class! – the more do workers
suffer under the hierarchical and despotic work organisation at
the factory. The stronger the contradiction between the
potential wealth which productive forces can create today and
the immeasurable waste and absurdity which capitalist production
and consumption implies, the more do workers tend to question
not only the way a capitalist factory is organised but also what
a capitalist factory produces. Recently, these trends found
striking expression not only during the May revolution in
France, but also at the Fiat plant in Italy where the workers
succeeded in preventing an increasing number of different types
of high-priced cars from being manufactured.
The logic of all these trends
puts the problem of workers’ control in the center of the
class struggle. Capitalists, bourgeois politicians and
ideologues, and reformist Social Democrats understand this in
their own way. That is why different schemes for “reform of
the enterprises,” for “co-management,”
“co-determination” and “participation” occupy the center
of the stage in practically all Western European countries. When
de Gaulle launched his “participation” demagogy, even the
bonapartist dictatorship of Franco in Spain proclaimed that it
was likewise in favor of working class participation in the
management of plants. As for Mr. Wilson, he didn’t wait a
month to jump on the same bandwagon.
But parallel to these various
schemes of mystification and deception is the growing awareness
in working class circles that the problem of workers’ control
is the key “social question” under neo-capitalism. Questions
of wages and shorter working hours are important; but what is
much more important than problems of the distribution of income
is to decide who should command the machines and who should
determine investments, who should decide what to produce and how
to produce it. British and Belgian trade unions have started to
agitate these questions on a large scale; they have been debated
in Italy at the factory level and by many left groupings. In
West Germany, Sweden, Norway and Denmark they are increasingly
subjects of debates in radical working class circles. And the
May revolution in France was a clarion call for these ideas
emanating from 10 million workers.
There remains the last
objection. Have the monopolists and their agents unlimited
powers of manipulating the ideology and consciousness of the
working class, and can they not succeed in preventing revolt,
especially successful revolt, notwithstanding growing
socio-economic contradictions?
Marxists have recognised the
possibility of “manipulation” for a long time. Marx wrote
about the artificially induced needs and consumption of the
workers a hundred and twenty-five years ago. Marxists have many
times reiterated that the “ruling ideology of each society is
the ideology of the ruling class.” One of the key ideas of
Lenin’s What Is to be Done? is the
recognition of the fact that, through their own individual
effort and even through elementary class struggle on a purely
economic and trade-union level, workers cannot free themselves
from the influence of bourgeois and petty-bourgeois ideology.
The classical socialist labor
movement tried to achieve such an ideological emancipation
through a constant process of organisation, education and
self-action. But even during its heyday it didn’t rally more
than a minority fraction of the working class. And if one looks
at the extremely modest proportions that Marxist education
assumed in mass socialist parties like the German or Austrian
Social Democracy before World War I (not to speak of the French
CP before World War II), if one looks at the figures of
subscribers to the theoretical magazines or students at study
camps or workers’ universities in those organisations, one can
easily understand that even then they merely scratched the
surface.
Of course things have become
worse since the classical labor movement started to degenerate
and stopped inoculating the working class vanguard in any
consistent manner against the poison of bourgeois ideas. The
dikes collapsed, and aided by modern mass media, bourgeois and
petty-bourgeois ideology have penetrated deeply into broad
layers of the working class, including those organised in mass
Social-Democratic and Communist parties.
But one should guard against
losing a sense of proportion in respect to this problem. After
all, the working class movement arose in the 19th century under
conditions where the mass of workers were far more dominated by
the ideas of the ruling class than they are today. One has only
to compare the hold of religion on workers in large parts of
Europe, or the grip of nationalism on the French working class
after the experience of the great French revolution, to
understand that what looks like a new problem today is in
reality as old as the working class itself.
In the last analysis the
question boils down to this: Which force will turn out to be
stronger in determining the worker’s attitude to the society
he lives in, the mystifying ideas he receives, yesterday in the
church and today through TV, or the social reality he confronts
and assimilates day after day through practical experience? For
historical materialists, to pose the question this way is to
answer it, although the struggle itself will say the last word.
Finally, one should add that,
while “manipulation” of the workers’ consciousness and
dreams is apparently constant, so after all is the apparent
stability of bourgeois society. It goes on living under
“business as usual.” But a social revolution is not a
continuous or gradual process; it is certainly not “business
as usual.” It is precisely a sudden disruption of social
continuity, a break with customs, habits and a traditional way
of life.
The problems of the
revolutionary potential of the working class cannot be answered
by references to what goes on every day or even every year;
revolutions do not erupt every day. The revolutionary potential
of the working class can be denied only if one argues that the
sparks of revolt which have been kindled in the working class
mass through the experience of social injustice and social
irrationality are smothered forever; if one argues that the
patient and obstinate propaganda and education by revolutionary
vanguard organisations cannot have a massive effect among the
workers anywhere, anytime, whatever may be the turn of objective
events. After all, it is enough that the flame is there to
ignite a combustible mass once every 15 or 20 years for the
system ultimately to collapse. That’s what happened in Russia.
That’s what the May revolution in France has shown can happen
in Western Europe too.
These epoch-making May events
allow us to draw a balance sheet of long-term trends which
confirm every proposition I have tried to defend here today.
After 20 years of neo-capitalism, functioning under classical
conditions, with a “planning board” which is cited as a
model for all imperialist countries, with a state television
system which has perfected a system of mass manipulation to
uphold the ruling class and party, with a foreign policy
accepted by a large majority of the masses, in May 1968 there
were in France twice as many strikers as ever before in the
history of the working class of that country; they used much
more radical forms of struggle than in 1936, in 1944-46 or in
1955; they not only raised the slogan of workers’ control,
workers’ management and workers’ power more sharply than
ever before, but started to put it in practice in a dozen big
factories and several large towns. In the face of this
experience it is hard to question the revolutionary potential of
the working class under neo-capitalism any more. In the face of
this experience it is hard to question the prediction that
France, which is the politically classical country of bourgeois
society, in the same way as Britain and the United States are
its economically classical countries, is showing the whole
Western world and not least the United States a preview of its
own future. De te fabula narratur! [The story being
told is about you!]
We have no time here to examine
the interconnection between the workers’ struggle for
socialism in the Western metropolises and the liberation
struggle of the colonial and semi-colonial countries as well as
the struggle for socialist democracy in the countries of Central
and Eastern Europe. These interconnections are manifold and
obvious. There are also direct causal links between the upsurge
of an independent revolutionary leadership in the Cuban and
Latin American revolution, the heroic struggle of the Vietnamese
people against US imperialist aggression, and the emergence of a
new youth vanguard in the West, which, at least in Western
Europe, through the transmission belt of working class youth,
has started to influence directly the development of the class
struggle.
The main striking feature here
has a more general and abstract character: the reemergence of
active internationalism in the vanguard of the working class.
The international concentration and centralisation of capital,
especially through the creation of the “multinational
corporation,” gave capital an initial advantage over a working
class movement hopelessly divided between national and sectional
unions and parties. But now, in France, at one blow, the
advanced workers have cleaned the field of the rot accumulated
over decades of confusion and defeat. They have cut through the
underbrush of bourgeois nationalism and bourgeois Europeanism
and have come out into the wide open space of international
brotherhood.
The fraternal unity in strikes
and demonstrations of Jewish and Arab, Portuguese and Spanish,
Greek and Turkish, French and foreign workers, in a country
which has probably been more plagued by xenophobia over the last
20 years than any other in Europe, triumphantly culminated in
60,000 demonstrators shouting before the Gare de Lyon: “We are
all German Jews.” Already a first echo has come from Jerusalem
itself where Jewish students demonstrated with the slogan: “We
are all Palestinian Arabs!” Never have we seen anything like
this, on such a scale, and these initial manifestations warrant
the greatest confidence in the world which will emerge when the
working class, rejuvenated after two decades of slumber, will
move to take power.
Most of you know that, both
through political conviction and as a result of objective
analysis of present world reality, I firmly believe that we are
living in the age of permanent revolution. This revolution is
inevitable because there is such a tremendous gap between what
man could make of our world, with the power which science and
technology have placed in his hands, and what he is making of it
within the framework of a decaying, irrational social system.
This revolution is imperative in order to close that gap and
make this world a place in which all human beings, without
distinction as to race, color or nationality, will receive the
same care as the rulers today devote to space rockets and
nuclear submarines.
What the socialist revolution
is all about, in the last analysis, is faith in the
unconquerable spirit of revolt against injustice and oppression
and confidence in the ability of mankind to build a future for
the human race. Coming from a continent which went through the
nightmares of Hitler and Stalin, and emerged hardly a generation
later holding high the banner of social revolution, of
emancipation of labor, of workers’ democracy, of proletarian
internationalism, and witnessing in France more youth rallying
around that banner than at any time since socialist ideas were
born, I believe that faith is fully justified.
|