With the end of the war, the
Soviet “buffer” countries. entered a period of political,
economic and social paroxysms, which was far from ended with the
constitution of the governments known as “people’s
democracies.” To be able to esti.mate the real significance of
the transformations undergone by these countries during the last
two years, it is first of all necessary to know the facts. Now,
working-class public opinion in general is unfamiliar with the
economic evolution of these countries regardless of whether it
is deceived by the will-of-the-wisps of Stalinist propaganda or
whether it accepts preconceived schemas as conforming to the
truth. That is why we believe it to be useful to assemble as
much data as possible on the economic evolution of the
“buffer” countries which can serve as the basis for a
Marxist evaluation of the recent transformations experienced by
these countries.
It is necessary, however, to
preface this exposition with two notes of caution. We have
deliberately excluded from this study all facts relating to the
economy of Finland and Albania which formally should be included
among the “buffer” countries. As far as Albania is
concerned, the extremely backward character of this small
country creates economic problems for it which bear only the
remotest resemblance to those confronted by the other countries
of Eastern Europe. Finland, although tied by a 20-year mutual
assistance and friendship pact and by clauses in the armistice
to the Soviet zone of influence, also has gone through a very
special evolution. During the summer of 1948 this led to the
elimination of the Stalinists from the government and to the
formation of the homogeneous and minority government led by the
Social Democrat, Fagerholm. Since then Finland has passed
through a violent social crisis which calls to mind the one in
France and Italy and deserves a separate study. In any case, it
does not enter into a study of relatively parallel tendencies of
development in the six other “buffer” countries.
Our second note of caution
relates to the validity of the data. We have tried to keep
strictly to official and semi-offiicial sources, that is in
general those of a Stalinist or Stalinophile character. But the
objectivity of the statistics and economic references of a
country is in direct ratio to its general cultural level and in
inverse ratio to the economic difficulties it experiences; and
both because of incompetence as well as self-interest, the
governments of the “buffer” countries are incapable of
presenting complete and verifiable facts. It is necessary
therefore to take all the figures we adduce with reservations
and never to lose sight of the fact that the essential elements
of economic reality can elude a study based upon official
figures since the latter simply conceal all evidence concerning
economic reality.
The principal scourge which has
visited the economy of the countries in the Soviet “buffer”
zone since the end of the war is inflation. The inflationist
tendency of their economy was already manifest during the war as
a consequence of the enormous cost of armaments, of the
occupation and of the devastation experienced in one form or
another in these six countries. The following table shows the
huge expansion of money in circulation:
CURRENCY
INFLATION
June 1939 and Dec. 1945
(in millions) |
Date |
Bulgaria
(levas) |
Hungary
(pengos) |
Poland
(zlotys) |
Rumania
(lei) |
Czechoslovakia
(crowns) |
Yugoslavia
(dinars) |
June 1939 |
2,891 |
885 |
1,848 |
38,683 |
10,740 |
6,921 |
Dec. 1945 |
69,921 |
765,446 |
26,319 |
1,212,925 |
120,000* |
350,000* |
* April,
1945 |
This major inflation of the
volume of money naturally let loose the train of familiar evils:
raising of prices, lowering of real wages, lowering of
productivity, scarcity of primary necessities, barter, inventory
accumulation by industry and wholesale trade, speculation,
flight of capital, etc. Even before the coalition governments,
which were formed in these countries after the armistice, could
think of remedying this situation a new set of conditions
aggravated inflation in most of them and caused a complete
monetary collapse. These were the cost of Russian occupation;
the reparations imposed on the countries which had formerly been
allied to Nazi Germany; the extreme dearth of foodstuffs or the
famine resulting from the successive crop failures in 1945-46
and in 1946-47 caused by severe drought and floods in all the
“buffer” countries (Yugoslavia and Bulgaria were less
affected than the others); the economic consequences of the
first social changes (the first wave of nationalizations and
agrarian reform) which, in the beginning, in all these countries
caused a stagnation and even a drying up of industrial and
agricultural production. Here is an illustration of this in the
figures for agricultural production:
PRODUCTION
OF BREAD GRAIN
(thousands of tons) |
Date |
Bulgaria |
Hungary |
Poland |
Rumania |
Czechoslovakia |
Yugoslavia |
1934-38 (aver.) |
1,787 |
2,917 |
8,531 |
3,749 |
3,148 |
2,636 |
1946 |
1,632 |
1,551 |
3,328 |
1,671 |
2,437 |
1,973 |
1947 |
1,410 |
1,690 |
3,478 |
1,755 |
1,732 |
2,300 |
PRODUCTION OF FORAGE
(thousands of tons) |
Date |
Bulgaria |
Hungary |
Poland |
Rumania |
Czechoslovakia |
Yugoslavia |
1934-38 (aver.) |
1,215 |
3,184 |
4,076 |
6,768 |
2,537 |
5,407 |
1946 |
775 |
2,013 |
1,774 |
1,572 |
1,885 |
1,949 |
1947 |
1,184 |
3,050 |
2,127 |
5,000 |
1,602 |
4,595 |
In face of the enormous volume
of money in circulation, the almost complete disappearance of
the circulation of commodities resulted in a constant
depreciation of money, which in turn became the essential cause
for the aggravation of the inflation. Monetary reform thus
became an imperative need in all these countries as the point of
departure for economic recovery.
They undertook this reform in a
hand-to-mouth manner under widely different circumstances,
impelled by conjunctural considerations in each of the national
economies.
POLAND limited
itself to a pure and simple currency conversion in January 1945.
Monetary circulation which had reached 26,319,000,000 zlotys in
December 1945 climbed to 60,066,000,000 in December 1946 and to
91,483,000,000 in December 1947. It was only in the course of
1948 that a relative monetary stabilization took place. (We will
return to this later.)
YUGOSLAVIA
undertook a monetary reform after “the liberation” in April
1945. Currency conversion, the confiscation of war profits and
the tax on fortunes accumulated during the war reduced monetary
circulation at one blow from 350 billion dinars in April 1945 to
6 billion in August 1945.
CZECHOSLOVAKIA,
after having passed through an intermediary stage of
amalgamating the different currencies in the former Sudeten
provinces (annexed by Hitler), in Bohemia-Moravia (former German
protectorate) and in Slovakia (formerly an independent state),
turned to monetary stabilization in November 1945. Currency
conversion was limited to 500 crowns per person and the sum of a
month’s wages for all workers and employees in the factories.
The remainder was blocked in the form of accounts against the
“funds for monetary liquidation” which were progressively
unfrozen after an inquiry into the origin of personal fortunes.
These “funds” comprised a mass of real goods (goods sold by
the enemy, German and Hungarian credit, revenue from a tax on
the growth of capital during the war) and, as a result, accounts
could be unfrozen without appreciably augmenting monetary
circulation. This was fixed at 24,233,000,000 crowns in December
1945, at 45,589,000,000 in December 1946, and at 58,539,000,000
in December 1947 which appeared as relatively normal, given the
increase in production.
Runaway
Inflation in Hungary
HUNGARY
experienced a complete monetary collapse. The exorbitant
character of Russian reparations and the enormous costs of
occupation played an important role in this collapse. The price
index, taking August 31, 1939 as 100, had jumped to 2,431 in
October 1945, 41,478 in December 1945, 435,887 in February 1946,
35,798,361 in April 1946, 862,317 million as of June 1-15, 1946,
3,006,254 billion as of July 1-7, 1946; 399,623
quadrillion as of July 24-31, 1946.
On August 1, 1946, the
Hungarian government took measures for monetary stabilization,
abolishing the old currency – the pengo – and replacing it
by a new money – the florint. The scope of the inflation had
even surpassed that of Germany in 1923 as is very clearly
indicated by the rate of exchange which was fixed at:
1 florint to
400,000,000,000,000,000,000,000,000,000 pengos.
The exchange made for all money
in circulation at first brought the price level down to around 2
to 2% times the prewar level (in Czechoslovakia, after currency
conversion the level of prices was arbitrarily fixed at 3 times
the pre-war level). The new currency rapidly stabilized,
monetary circulation rose to 375 million florint at the end of
August 1946, to 968 million at the end of December 1946 and to
1,992 million at the end of December 1947, which corresponded
approximately ta the increase of production.
BULGARIA,
although not experiencing a runaway inflation of the same kind
as Hungary, saw its volume of currency multiply at the end of
1945 to about 2,500 percent over the pre-war level. Moreover,
the situation was complicated by the circulation of treasury
bonds bearing 3 percent interest which immediately caused (in
line with the well-known economic law, “bad money drives out
good”) their complete disappearance from circulation and
consequent hoarding by the population. The government therefore
decided, on March 7, 1947, to initiate the redemption of all
notes in the denomination of 200, 250, 500, 1,000, and 5,000
levas as well as all treasury bonds, allowing only 2,000 levas
per person, more than half the sum total of the monthly paycheck
in the factories.
Contrary to the other
“buffer” countries, they committed the fatal error at the
time of monetary reform of ordering the closing of stores for
two days after the proclamation of the currency reform. This
naturally led to a complete disappearance of all prime
necessities for many long weeks in the big cities. The Bulgarian
government, applying a policy of freezing big monetary fortunes
in the form of bank accounts, reduced the total sum of money in
circulation from 74,206 million levas at the end of 1946 to
72,684 million at the end of 1947.
RUMANIA
experienced a similar evolution to that of Hungary. Monetary
circulation of the lei rose from 38,683 million in June 1939 to
1,212,925 million in December 1945, and to 6,117,603 million in
December 1946. The rate of exchange for the dollar on the black
market which had been 30,000 lei to the dollar at the beginning
of 1946 climbed to more than 2 million lei by the middle of
1947. A vast speculation also ensued with gold coin which were
minted in 1945. Monetary reform of August 15, 1947 fixed the
rate of exchange at 20,000 old lei for one new one. The maximum
that could be exchanged varied between 1.5 and 5 million old lei
and the remaining notes were blocked without interest. As in
Bulgaria, a moratorium was proclaimed. Money in circulation at
the end of 1947 rose to 24,536 million new lei.
Three Common
Characteristics.
All these operations have
three, important features in common:
(a) They involved violent
actions convulsing the life of the whole population and
“stabilizing” it at an extremely low level. The immediate
interests of the workers were sacrificed to the needs of a
“stable currency,” the point of departure for economic
reconstruction. Later on, we will see the concrete ,
consequences of this reform on the proletariat of countries like
Hungary and Rumania.
(b) In the hands of governments
dominated by the Stalinists, monetary reform became a specific
instrument for redistribution of national wealth and income.
Each time those hardest hit were the hoarders, the well-to-do
peasants, black market speculators, the small and middle
industrialists who were unable to acquire raw materials, the
rentiers, people living from fixed incomes, etc. In some
concrete cases, especially in Yugoslavia and to a lesser degree
in Hungary, monetary reform was one of the essential instruments
of carrying out a virtual expropriation of the middle class
which did not flee the country.
(c) Monetary reform
concentrated an enormous volume of liquid capital in the hands
of the state and automatically gave it control over the entire
banking system. The state became the prime regulator and
distributor of all industrial credit. In this sense, currency
conversion became the effective point of departure for the
various hybrid forms of planning introduced one after the other
by all the “buffer” countries. At the same time there was
concentrated in the hands of the state the initial funds for
accumulation and investment permitting the execution of the
“plans.”
The First
Anti-Capitalist Measures
In 1945-46, Poland,
Czechoslovakia, Yugoslavia and to a lesser degree Bulgaria,
experienced a first wave of nationalizations which had very
clear common characteristics. They were, at the time, the result
of the revolutionary upsurge of the proletariat in these
countries (occupation of factories later nationalized), the
physical disappearance of the former proprietors (the question
of German property in countries which had been at war with
Germany), and of the pre-war structure of these countries where
the state sector was always very important because of the
weakness of native private capital.
However, this first wave of
nationalizations in all these countries permitted the survival
of a very important private capitalist .sector not only in trade
and the credit system but also in industry. Thus before the
second wave of nationalizations in 1948, 20 percent of Czech
industrial production and almost 40 percent of Polish industrial
production was accounted for by the- private sector. In Hungary,
except for heavy industry in which two-thirds of production was
accounted for by stateized enterprises, private industry
controlled at least 80 percent of industrial production up to
the beginning of 1948. As for Bulgaria, Cyril Lazarov wrote in
the central organ of the Stalinist party, Rabotnitchesko
Delo, October 31, 1948:
Despite the defeat which was
suffered on the economic plane, the capitalist class
nevertheless maintained commanding positions in the economic
life of the country ... as much in industry as in trade and
agriculture. In 1947, the situation in industry took the
following form: the share.of the cooperative sector in the total
value of production was 11 percent while the private sector rose
to 65 percent ... During this year there were 740 persons in our
country who accounted for a total income of more than a billion
leva.
In Rumania, the whole of
industry remained private property save for the stateized
National Bank and the various mixed companies or German
properties seized by the Russians.
It was only in 1948, and
obviously according to a preconceived plan, that a second wave
of nationalizations carried out in a purely bureaucratic fashion
by decrees in all six countries completely eliminated private
capital in the banking sector, eliminating it in large part in
the industrial sector and severely curbing it in trade.
The Second
Wave of Nationalization
BULGARIA:
Through a decree proposed on December 23, 1947 and later
adopted, 7,000 industrial enterprises (practically all industry)
were nationalized. Only 500 of these enterprises employed more
than 50 workers. All the others were small. The enterprises
working with foreign capital (with the exception of the former
German properties seized by the Russian state) were included .in
the nationalization. The former proprietors were indemnified in
principal by state interest-bearing bonds redeemable in 20
years. But all proprietors who had put their factories at the
disposal of the police in the struggle against the partisans
between March 1, 1941 and the end of 1944, were excluded from
this indemnification. So also were those considered foreign
agents or spies or those who had participated in political
activity against the new regime beginning .with August 1944. In
practice, this clause limited the application of indemnification
measures to foreign capital. This quasi-total nationalization of
industry was accompanied or followed by complete nationalization
of the banks and of foreign trade as well as by important
measures of nationalization in domestic trade. In the above
article in Rabotnitchesko Delo, Cyril Lazarov
puts the state share of wholesale trade at 64 percent and its
share in retail trade at 22.3 percent.
HUNGARY: On
April 39, 1948, Parliament passed a law nationalizing all
mining’ and metallurgical enterprises and all enterprises
engaged in the production and distribution of electric power
which employed more than 100 persons. Moreover, certain smaller
enterprises occupying key positions in their sector were also
nationalized. With the exception of the former German properties
seized by the Soviet state, all enterprises in which foreign
capital participated up to 50 percent were excluded from
nationalization. Indemnification of former proprietors was
provided without the limiting clauses applied in Bulgaria, and
the Supreme Economic Council immediately gave advances on these
indemnities to bourgeois families applying for them.
The over-all result of these
nationalization measures is the following -division of the
working force employed by Hungarian industry in the various
sectors: 73.8 per cent in the state sector; 5.3 per cent in the
communal sector; 3.6 per cent in the mixed companies; 18.8 per
cent in the private sector. The whole banking system, as well as
around 20 per cent of wholesale trade, were later also
nationalized.
Measures
Taken in Poland
POLAND: A
series of nationalization measures during the years 1947 and
1948 resulted in the increase of the state’s role in the
industry of the country from 60 to 80 per cent. However, 40 per
cent of building construction was carried on by private firms (Kurier
Godziecny, July 14, 1948). At the same time, the
development of state commerce saw a vigorous rise, especially in
1948, and was the essential means for the stabilization of the
prices. On the other hand, the part of private capital in
foreign trade which was nil in 1947 has been constantly
augmented and now amounts to between 10 and 15 per cent. The
total share of the private sector in retail trade is estimated
at approximately 70 per cent. Finally, the banking system was
completely nationalized by the law of November 12, 1948. The two
banks which took the form of joint stock companies after the
first banking reform following: the “liberation” were
closed. It is true that important private participation is
permitted in “The Bank of Foreign Commerce,” a joint stock
company in which the state, however, holds the major interest.
RUMANIA: In a
surprise move on July 11, 1948, the Rumanian government proposed
a law providing for important nationalizations and obtaining its
passage after a discussion which lasted three hours. As a result
of this measure the following were nationalized: all oil
companies including those in which foreign capital participated
(with the exception of the mixed Soviet-Rumanian company); two
big factories belonging to the British Unilever trust, the
banks, the insurance companies, the railroads, the radio and the
telephone companies, the shipping companies and all ships,
making a total of 702 enterprises of all types. All factories in
the metallurgical industry employing more than 100 workers were
nationalized. Similarly for all factories in the lumber industry
using more than 20 horsepower and all factories in the textile
industry using more than 100 horsepower, etc. The former
proprietors are to be indemnified by state bonds redeemable
against profits earned by the newly nationalized enterprises.
Those owners who were guilty of sabotaging Rumanian economy and
those who had illegally left the country are deprived of
compensation.
CZECHOSLOVAKIA:
The state sector which comprised around 60% of industry was
considerably enlarged after the February 1948 crisis. Included
in the nationalization were: numerous enterprises in the
building and food industries, big hotels and restaurants,
tourist centers, the musical instrument industry, hospitals, the
printing and book industry, the transport system, the banks, all
foreign trade and domestic wholesale trade. The private sector
comprised only 8% of industry but still retained its dominant
position in retail trade.
YUGOSLAVIA: A
law passed on April 28, 1948 nationalized approximately 3,100
private establishments including the following: 10 mines, 65
small power plants, 200 printing plants, 100 movie houses, 350
sanitariums, hospitals, hotels, bathhouses, etc., all ships or
vessels carrying more than 50 passengers. Compensation of former
proprietors in the form of state bonds without any limiting
clauses was provided for. Moreover, former proprietors are
permitted to retain up to 30% in liquid assets of the newly
nationalized enterprises and to receive the remainder of liquid
assets in state bonds. This law virtually nationalizing all
small industry above the artisan level was followed by measures
taken on May 21-28, 1948, expropriating 1,105 merchants in
Belgrade who were accused of speculation. All wholesale trade
was thus nationalized.
Remaining
Strength of Bourgeoisie
What conclusions can be drawn
from these various measures as to the specific weight of the
bourgeoisie in the economic life of the buffer countries ? As
late as the end of 1947, only in Yugoslavia was the industrial
bourgeoisie completely eliminated except for small
establishments; in Czechoslovakia and in Poland, the bourgeoisie
retained strong positions in light industry; in Hungary it still
occupied a preponderant position except for the metallurgical
sector and the mines; in Rumania and in Bulgaria, it still
dominated practically all sectors. Moreover the commercial
bourgeoisie in a manner of speaking retained all its positions
in these countries.
Today the situation is
drastically modified. In Yugoslavia and Bulgaria, the industrial
bourgeoisie has been completely eliminated and the commercial
bourgeoisie reduced to small retail stores. In Poland and
Czechoslovakia, some secondary sectors of small industry (a
strong position in the Polish building industry) and wholesale
trade remain in its hands and a preponderant position in retail
trade. In Hungary it retains a slightly less important position
in light industry (75% of the clothing industry; 35% of the
paper industry; 32% of the chemical industry, etc.). In Rumania
it preserves a preponderant position in medium-sized industry in
several sectors.
However in none of those
countries can we speak of a disappearance of the bourgeoisie,
not even of its reduction to a point comparable in Russia during
the period of the NEP. For example in Yugoslavia which has
pushed nationalizations the furthest, D. Vukovich writes (Borba,
November 25, 1948) that the share of the capitalists in the
national income in 1948 will rise considerably to 11.22%; that
of the workers to 25.07%. Now if we are to believe official
statistics, the number of Yugoslav workers is about to pass the
million mark. Since it is extremely difficult to conceive of the
existence of hundreds of thousands of capitalists after all the
nationalization measures, the logical conclusion to be drawn
from these figures is that there still remains an enormous
disproportion of income between the workers and the capitalist
elements who are “hard pressed by the government.”
Reconstruction
and Industrialization
The struggle against inflation
opened the road to economic revival. The successive
nationalization measures have placed this revival within a
specific framework. How successful has it been to date?
All six countries in the Soviet
buffer zone, covered in this study, have tried to elaborate a
plan of reconstruction and industrialization; This began when
general economic conditions made this possible; The suppression
of runaway inflation was the first indispensable prerequisite
for the elaboration of these plans. It is also clear that a
minimum of preliminary recovery permitted the state at a minimum
to find the means to feed the working class enough to be able to
demand from it a certain increase in productivity, the
touchstone of all the “plans.” That is generally the reason
for the considerable lag between the beginning of economic
revival and the publication of the drafts of the plans.
The first two plans announced,
the Polish three-year plan and the Czech two-year plan, were
both to take effect on January 1, 1947. Reconstruction was their
principal objective: in fact, the annexation by Poland of the
“western territories” (former Silesia and German Pomerania)
and the expulsion of the German Sudeten population from
Czechoslovakia imposed the task of internal colonization on both
of .these countries. This took the form both of the resettlement
of peasants in the newly acquired areas and of large industrial
investments in these regions. These plans therefore in essence
aimed, at returning, under completely altered social and
national conditions, to the prewar level of production in those
regions which now formed part of their national territory.
The projected investments are
large and should absorb 20% to 23% of the national income; a
very high percentage, higher than that of the first Russian
five-year plans. The division between agriculture and industry
and between heavy and light industry, in both cases is
especially favorable to heavy industry, agriculture receiving
only 7% to 9% of the appropriations in Czechoslovakia and from
13-15% in Poland.
The Bulgarian two-year plan
went into effect on April 1, 1947. It is of a very different
type given the economic conditions of this country. In relation
to national income, the rate of investment is much lower: 9% for
the first year, 3% for the second. Although the emphasis was put
on an accelerated industrialization which should permit Bulgaria
to rapidly surpass the extremely low level of industrial
production in 1938, the plan has an essentially agricultural
objective and consists in an attempt to return to the 1938 level
of agricultural production.
The Yugoslav
Five-Year Plan
The Yugoslav five-year plan
which went into effect on April 30, 1947, after a long period of
discussion and elaboration, has extremely ambitious objectives.
It provides for the industrialization of the entire country
aiming both at endowing the Yugoslav Federation with a heavy
industry and with giving an impulsion to the development of
light industry in the particularly backward federated republics.
The projected investments are extremely high: they absorb 42% of
the national income! The plan provides only 8% of investments
for agriculture and nevertheless envisages a total
transformation of agriculture.
The Hungarian three-year plan,
elaborated at the same time as currency reform, was to go into
effect immediately after this reform on August 1, 1947. Its
objectives are much more flexible than those in the other plans.
The sum total of investments provided covers 10% of the national
income. (It must be noted that Russian reparations constitute a
charge on the Hungarian economy which prevents a major increase
in the rate of accumulation.) 30% of these investments are
allocated for agriculture and only 26.5% for industry. The
Hungarian plan aims especially at the reestablishment of the
pre-war structure of the country’s economy, at the augmenting
of agricultural production and at the development of light
industry. Of all the plans it appears to be the only one which
takes most into consideration the necessity of immediately
improving the standard of living of the workers, Moreover we
will see later that together with Poland, Hungary is the one
country in the buffer zone which actually reached the 1938 level
in 1948.
Finally, Rumania, bogged down
in inextricable financial difficulties, and had not yet
succeeded by; 1947 in getting industry started, contented itself
with promulgating a plan (June 15, 1947) for economic and
financial recovery whose principal aim was the struggle against
inflation. It was only on December 27, 1948 that the Rumanian
Parliament passed a law promulgating a “one-year plan” which
provided a 40 per cent increase of industrial production for
1949. This would place production above the 1938 level.
Czechoslovakia and Bulgaria,
whose plans ended in 1948, elaborated two five-year plans in the
course of the current year providing for an accelerated
industrial upswing. We will return to these plans in the
conclusion of this survey but we will content ourselves here
with noting that the Bulgarian “super-industrialization,”
which is quite similar to the one in Yugoslavia, has received a
supreme benediction from Stalin in person, just as the Yugoslav
five-year plan had been received with enthusiasm by Pravda
before the conflict with Tito!
How the
Plans Were Carried Out
To what extent were the
provisions of the various plans realized by the end of 1948?
In BULGARIA
only 77 per cent of the goal for 1947 was attained. (Terpetchev
in Izgrev, Feb. 15 and 24, 1948.) The greatest
lag was in agriculture, especially in products for export
(raisins and fruit). As a result, the figures for 1948 have been
revised: industry is to surpass the 1947 level by 36 per cent
and agriculture is to surpass the 1947 level by 86 per cent,
which puts the objectives for 1948 slightly above the initial
objectives for 1947. These have been realized for industry where
the index of production reached 170 (1938 equals 100). But the
results for agriculture were far from positive. Rabotnitchesko
Delo for October 15 and 17, 1948 indicates that,
despite the good harvest for the year, only one district on
October 10th had delivered a volume of products corresponding to
the goals set, 13 districts had delivered between 80 and 90 per
cent of these goals and numerous districts had not even
fulfilled half of their quota.
Industrial production in 1947
in HUNGARY witnessed a rise in heavy industry
and a serious lag in light industry. While heavy industry had
already surpassed the 1938 level, at the end of 1947 Hungary was
only producing 2,000,000 pairs of shoes as against 4.7 million
in 1938. It produced 140 million meters of cotton cloth as
against 184.8 million in 1938. In November 1948, according to
Rakosi, the index for mining and metallurgy industry was 137,
for the chemical industry, 123, and for textiles 110 (1938
equals 100). As for Hungarian agriculture, it experienced a
complete recovery from the drought and now enjoys a period of
prosperity.
POLAND: The
industrial production of Poland, basing itself on the new
Silesian basin, attained the 1938 level during the course of
1947, then progressively improved to 130 and to 140 by the
middle and end of 1948, Here also a considerable lag separates
the sector providing means of consumption and the one providing
means of production. Polish agriculture, still operating at a
deficit in 1947, succeeded in 1948 in satisfying all the
national needs and has embarked upon a vast program of the
export of cattle raising products.
RUMANIA: Here
there are few of no figures but from all the evidence
Rumania has been the most retarded of all the “buffer”
countries in its economic revival. The 1938 level of production
has not been attained in either industry or agriculture.
CZECHOSLOVAKIA:
As the most advanced of the “buffer” countries, it is also
the one which has experienced the most complicated organic
difficulties in the development of the productive forces. The
index of production, which had reached 87 in 1947 (1937 equals
100) leveled off at around 100 in 1948; this level was reached
in the first months of the year. It should be noted that the
output of the consumer goods industries was hardly 80 per cent
of 1938. Agriculture experienced a serious crisis which we will
deal with later on.
Finally, YUGOSLAVIA
has certainly experienced industrialization at a rate far
superior to the other “buffer” countries. Tito claimed in a
recent speech that the goals of the plan for 1948 were fulfilled
100 per cent. However, the above-cited article by D. Vukovich in
Borba sets the rate of investment in relation
to national income in 1948 at 38.33 per cent although the plan
provided for a rate of 42 per cent.
In general, economic recovery
was therefore realized within the prescribed framework but with
agriculture generally lagging behind industry.
January 1, 1949.
|