I
would like to thank Mary C. Malloy and the discussants and
participants in the seminar on “The Contribution of Ernest
Mandel to Marxist Theory” (held at the Ernest Mandel Study
Center of the International Institute for Research and
Education, Amsterdam, The Netherlands, July 4-6, 1996) for their
comments on an earlier draft of this essay.
The
emergence and growth of bureaucracy, the non-propertied
officialdom of various organizations, over the last two hundred
years has been the subject of considerable discussion among
social scientists. Conventional, bourgeois sociology argues that
bureaucratic hierarchies are an unavoidable feature of modern
societies, whose size and complexity preclude any possibility of
popular democratic control over political, economic and social
life. Max Weber saw bureaucracy as the most rational and
effective mode of organizing the activities of large numbers of
people because it ensured decision-making according to general
rules rather than the whims of officials, cultivated trained
“experts”, and reduced the possibilities of corruption and
nepotism.[1]
Robert Michels extended Weber’s theory of bureaucracy,
originally developed to analyze the officialdom of the
capitalist state, to the study of the mass working class parties
and unions of the early twentieth century.[2] The
“iron law of oligarchy”, today embraced by social-democrats
and neo-Stalinists, purports that the growth and usurpation of
power by a layer of full-time officials are inevitable features
of mass working class parties and unions under capitalism and of
any post-capitalist social order.
Ernest Mandel’s work provides a powerful Marxian
alternative to the Stalinist, social-democratic and bourgeois
theories that deny the possibility of democratically organized
workers’ struggles and workers’ power in the modern world.
In a series of works,[3]
Mandel presented a complex, coherent and empirically well
grounded response to the notion that the arrogation of power by
a minority of officials and experts is the “inevitable”
result of complex, large-scale, modern social organization.
Mandel argued that bureaucracy is the product of specific,
historically limited relations among human beings and between
human beings and the natural world—of specific social
relations and material forces of production. Mandel’s theory
of bureaucracy provides a contemporary defense, extension and
deepening of the classical Marxist discussion of bureaucracy, in
particular the work of Rosa Luxemburg and Leon Trotsky.
For Mandel, the emergence of bureaucracies in both the
mass working class parties and unions under capitalism and in
the post-capitalist societies is rooted in the reproduction of
the social division of labor between mental-supervisory and
manual labor. Whether the product of the episodic character of
working class struggle under capitalism, or profound material
scarcity in the case of twentieth century post-revolutionary
societies, the persistent division between “head” work and
“hand” work gives rise to a layer of full-time officials who
administer either mass parties and unions or the post-capitalist
state apparatus. This layer, in most circumstances, evolves into
a distinct social layer with its own material interests,
politics, and ideology. The development of the bureaucracy does
not enhance the “efficiency” and effectivity of mass workers
organizations under capitalism or of centrally planned economic
life in the post-capitalist societies. Instead, the
officialdom’s monopoly of power undermines
the ability of the working class to either defend its most
immediate interests under capitalism or to build a viable
alternative to capitalism. Mandel’s theory of bureaucracy is
one of the central scientific foundations of the revolutionary
political project of working class self-activity,
self-organization and self-emancipation.
Our discussion of Mandel’s theory of bureaucracy is
divided into three parts. In the first, we will examine
Mandel’s analysis of the origins and role of the labor
bureaucracy in the capitalist social formations, and his theory
of the revolutionary workers’ organization as an alternative
to bureaucratic reformism. We will also assess Mandel’s
attempt to explain why, contrary to the expectation of
revolutionary Marxists, no truly mass revolutionary parties have
emerged in the advanced capitalist countries since the 1920s. In
the second part, we will review Mandel’s attempt to update and
refine Trotsky’s analysis of the bureaucracy in the
post-capitalist societies. Specifically we will grapple with the
issue of whether the bureaucracy’s relationship with the
working class constitutes a new mode of production, and whether
these regimes can be understood as “workers’ states” in
any meaningful, Marxian sense. We will conclude with a
discussion of the political importance of Mandel’s theory of
bureaucracy.
I.
THE LABOR BUREAUCRACY IN THE CAPITALIST SOCIAL FORMATIONS
The classical Marxist discussion of the labor bureaucracy
began as an attempt to explain the growth of reformism within
the mass socialist parties of the early twentieth century. The
leaders of the revolutionary left-wing of European socialism did
not merely criticize the theory and practice of the mainstream
of social-democracy, but attempted to uncover the social and
material roots of the labor movements’ conservatism and
ultimate capitulation to their national capitalist classes
during the first World War. Given the practical revolutionary
success of the Bolsheviks,
it was not surprising that Lenin’s thesis on the
degeneration of social democracy became, in Mandel’s words,
“the ‘dogma’ for revolutionary Marxists for nearly half a
century.”[4]
According to Lenin, the growth of reformism in the labor
movement in the advanced capitalist countries was the
ideological expression of the “labor aristocracy,” a
privileged minority of the western working class whose superior
standard of living came from a share of the “super profits”
extracted by the imperialist bourgeoisie in the colonies and
semi-colonies. This layer of workers supported the “petty-bourgeois
intellectuals” in the party and union apparatus who propagated
reformist and “social patriotic” politics before and during
World War I.[5]
Mandel was the first thinker in the revolutionary Marxist
tradition to reject explicitly Lenin’s notion of the “labor
aristocracy.” Mandel cites three important reasons for jettisoning the
notion that a layer of workers in the imperialist countries
share in the “super-profits” extracted from workers in the
“third world.” First,
the multinational corporations’ total profits from their
direct investments in Africa, Asia and Latin America can not
account for the wage bill of even the most well paid, unionized
workers in the industrialized countries. Put simply, workers in
the “third world” do not produce sufficient surplus value to
“bribe” a significant sector of the working class in the
Europe, the US or Japan. Second, the gap between the wages of
workers in the “north” and “south” is much greater than
wage differentials among workers in the “north.”
In other words, the
entire working classes of Europe,
the US and Japan are potential
“labor aristocracies.”
But, Mandel points out, these global wage differentials
are the result of the greater capital intensity (organic
composition of capital) and higher productivity of labor (rate
of surplus value) in the advanced capitalist social formations,
not some sharing of “super profits” between capital and
labor in the industrialized countries. Put simply, the better
paid workers of the “north” are more
exploited than the poorly paid workers of the “south.”
Finally, Mandel points out that some of the best paid
workers in Europe, the U.S. and Japan, especially those in the
metal working industries, were among the most militant and
radical proletarians, providing the mass base of the
revolutionary Communist parties of the 1920s and early 1930s.[6]
Mandel found a more fruitful Marxian discussion of the
labor bureaucracy under capitalism in the work of Rosa
Luxemburg.[7]
Luxemburg, well before either Lenin or Trotsky,
understood that the emergence and development of the trade union
and party officialdom was the key to German social-democracy’s
growing conservatism.[8] In the
wake of the Russian revolution of 1905, Luxemburg encountered
opposition to her advocacy of the “mass strike” as a tactic
for the German workers’ movement from both the openly
“revisionist” wing of the SPD led by Bernstein, and from the
“orthodox Marxist” leadership of the party around Kautsky
and Bebel. She concluded that the full-time party and union
officials’ hegemony over the SPD, not simply the influence of
middle class intellectuals, was the root of the entire
leadership’s refusal to countenance any activities other than
election campaigns and routinized collective bargaining. For
Luxemburg, this bureaucracy, once consolidated in the mass
working class institutions, placed greater importance upon the
preservation of the party and union apparatus than on any
attempt to deepen and extend the workers’ struggles.
Mandel located the origins of the labor bureaucracy in
the episodic and discontinuous character of working class
struggle under capitalism. For Mandel, the necessary condition
for the development of class consciousness is the self-activity
and self-organization of the workers themselves. It is the
experience of mass, collective and successful struggles against
capital and its state in the work place and the community that
opens layers of workers to radical and revolutionary political
ideas. When workers do not engage in mass struggle or suffer
defeats, they become open to conservative and reactionary ideas
as one section of the class makes a futile attempt to defend
their particular sectional (national, occupational,
racial-ethnic, gender) interests against other sectors of the
working class. In sum, it is the level of class militancy and
independence, not cultural influences like suburbanization,
television, films and the like, that determines the basic
parameters of class consciousness under capitalism. [9]
The working class cannot be, as whole, permanently active
in the class struggle. The entire working class cannot
consistently engage in strikes, demonstrations and other forms
of political activity because this class is separated from
effective possession of the means of production and is compelled
to sell their labor power to capital in order to survive. The
“actually existing” working class can only engage in mass
struggles as a class
in extraordinary, revolutionary or pre-revolutionary situations,
which, because of the structural position of wage labor under
capitalism, must be of short duration. Most of the time,
different segments of the working class become active in the
struggle against capitalism at different times.
In the wake of successful mass struggles, only a minority
of the workers remain consistently active. Most of this
“workers’ vanguard”—the layer of workers who “even
during a lull in the struggle...does not abandon the front lines
of the class struggle but continues the war, so to speak, ‘by
other means’”[10]--
preserves and transmits to newer workers the traditions of mass
struggle in the workplace or the community. However, a minority
of this “militant minority”, together with middle class
intellectuals who have access to cultural skills from which the
bulk of the working class is excluded, must take on
responsibility for administering the unions or political parties
created by periodic upsurges of mass activity. Mandel recognized
that “the development of mass political or trade-union
organizations is inconceivable without an apparatus of
full-timers and functionaries.”
However, he points out that the emergence of a layer of
full time officials brings with it the:
risk
that working-class organizations will themselves become divided
between layers exercising different functions. Specialization
can result in a growing monopoly of knowledge, of centralized
information. Knowledge is power, and a monopoly of it leads to
power over people... if not checked, [this can—CP] mean a real
division between new bosses and the bossed-over mass.[11]
During the unavoidable lulls in the class struggle, when
the vast majority of the working class is passive, the potential
for bureaucratization is actualized. Especially during
“long-waves” of capitalist growth, when most workers’
living standards and working conditions improve without
tumultuous, mass struggles, the officialdom of the mass workers
organizations can separate themselves from the rest of the
working class. Those workers who become officials of the unions
and political parties begin to experience conditions of life
very different from those who remain in the workplace. The new
officials find themselves freed from the daily humiliations of
the capitalist labor process. They are no longer subject to
either deskilled and alienated labor or the petty-despotism of
supervisors. Able to set their own hours, plan and direct
their own activities, and devote the bulk of their waking hours
to “fighting for the workers”, the officials seek to
consolidate these privileges and create new ones, in particular
incomes substantially higher than those of the workers they
purportedly represent. In defense of their privileges, which
become quite substantial as the unions and mass working class
parties gain a place in bourgeois society, the labor bureaucracy
excludes rank and file activists in the unions and parties from
any real decision making power.
The consolidation of the labor bureaucracy as a social
layer distinct and separate from the rest of the working class
under capitalism gives rise to its distinctive political
practice and world-view. The
preservation of the apparatus of the mass union or party,
as an end itself,
becomes the main objective of the labor bureaucracy. The labor
bureaucrats seek to contain working class militancy within
boundaries that do not threaten the continued existence of the
institutions which are the basis of the officials’ unique life
style. Thus the “dialectic of partial conquests”, the
possibility that new struggles may result in the destruction of
the mass organizations of the working class, buttress the labor
bureaucracy’s reliance on electoral campaigns and
parliamentary pressure tactics (“lobbying’) to win political
reforms, and strictly regimented collective bargaining to
increase wages and improve working conditions. Any and all
discussion, no less attempts to promote the tumultuous
self-activity and self-organization of working and oppressed
people in the forms of militant workplace actions, mass
political strikes or the like, must be quashed.[12]
At this point, the bureaucracy’s organizational fetishism (giving priority
the survival of the apparatus over new advances in the struggle)
grows into a substitutionism that demands the workers’
unquestioning obedience to
leaders who claim they know “what is best for the
workers.”
As Mandel never tired of pointing out, the reformist
substitution of electoral politics and routinized bargaining for
mass struggles ignores “the structural
character of the basic relations of production and of
political and social class power.[13]’
In other words, the politics of the labor bureaucracies in the capitalist
social formations are utopian
in the most negative sense of the word.[14]
The labor bureaucracies’ attempts to broker the struggle
between capital and labor, modifying very gradually the
relationship of forces in favor of the workers constantly
flounders on capitalism’s unavoidable crises of profitability
and the resulting intensification of the class struggle. The
history of both the classical social-democratic parties and the
Communist parties after 1935, when they began their
transformation into reformist parties,[15] sadly confirms the thoroughly unrealistic character of
the bureaucracy’s gradualism. During revolutionary and
pre-revolutionary crises, like those in Italy in 1920, Germany
during 1918-1923, Spain
and France in 1936-37, and Chile in 1970-73,
the social-democratic and Stalinist parties successfully
disorganized the workers’ struggles and organizations
(workers’ councils, factory committees and the like) in the
name of preserving bourgeois democracy and the past conquests of
the workers’ movement. Unfortunately, the derailing of mass
revolutionary struggles did not merely waste opportunities to
seize state power and begin the construction of a new democratic
and socialist order, but
opened the road to the forces of reaction. The Italian
fascists’ victory in 1921, the Nazi’s seizure of power in
1933, Franco’s military victory in 1939,
the collapse of the French Third Republic in 1940, and
Pinochet’s coup of September 11, 1973 were all the products of
the working class’ inability to seize power when the
opportunity presented itself. In sum, the labor bureaucracy’s
attempt to “self-limit” the workers’ struggles within the
boundaries of capitalist democracy facilitated the consolidation
of dictatorial and repressive forms of capitalist rule.[16]
The reformist substitution of electoral campaigns,
parliamentary pressure politics and bureaucratized collective
bargaining for working class and popular mass action has led to
profound disorganization and passivity in the ranks of
the labor movement in the west since the second World War. While
such bureaucratic forms of “struggle” were able to
“deliver the goods” in the form of higher wages, improved
benefits, stabilized working conditions and an expanding
“welfare state” during the “long wave” of expansion of
the 1950s and 1960s, this strategy proved completely inadequate
during the “long wave” of stagnation that began in the late
1960s. As the crisis of capitalist profitability deepened,
reformism’s substitutionism gave way to realpolitik—adapting
to the new “reality” of declining living and working
conditions. As Mandel pointed out:
..the
underlying assumption of present-day social-democratic
gradualism is precisely this: let the capitalists produce the
goods, so that governments can redistribute them in a just way.
But what if capitalist production demands more unequal, more
unjust distribution of the ‘fruits of growth’?
What if there is no economic growth at all as a result of
capitalist crisis? The
gradualists can then only repeat mechanically: there is no
alternative; there is no way out. [17]
Eschewing
militancy and direct action by workers and other oppressed
people, the labor bureaucracy and reformist politicians in the
west have no choice
but to make concessions to the employers’ offensive and to
administer capitalist state austerity. The spectacle of
reformist bureaucrats shunning the struggle for reforms has been
repeated across the capitalist world in the last two decades
with tragic results: from the Italian Communist party’s
embrace of austerity, to the concession bargaining of the US
AFL-CIO officials, to the Mitterand regimes’ budget cuts,
privatization and deregulation, to the subjugation of an
ANC-COSATU led government in post-apartheid South Africa to what
some have called the “sado-monetarism” of the IMF and World
Bank. Again, even the most moderate forms of social-democratic
gradualism prove to be profoundly utopian—unable to defend the
workers’ past
gains no less win significant new reforms during the crisis of
capitalist profitability.[18]
Given its roots in the necessarily episodic character of
mass struggle under capitalism, is the bureaucratization of the
mass organizations of the working class inevitable?
Clearly, Mandel’s theory of the labor bureaucracy in
the capitalist social formations lead us to the conclusion that
reformism will continue to be a problem in the workers’
movement until capitalism is overthrown internationally.
However, Mandel’s theory also identifies countervailing social
forces to, and safeguards against the bureaucratization of the
political parties and trade unions. In perhaps his greatest
political-theoretical contribution, his elaboration and
clarification of the Leninist theory of organization,[19]
Mandel demonstrates how the same episodic process of class
struggle that creates the environment for the growth of the
labor bureaucracy provides the human material for a mass,
revolutionary workers’ party. Out of the ebbs and flows of the
class struggle, a workers
vanguard is precipitated. The ability of a revolutionary
socialist nucleus to organize and eventually fuse with the most
active, militant and radical workers creates a variety of
potential counter-weights to the labor bureaucracy.
In non-revolutionary periods, non-socialist organizations
of “advanced workers” in organized and unorganized
workplaces—what in the US we call “rank and file’
currents—play an important role in keeping alive traditions of
militancy and solidarity in the workers’ movements and
fighting for effective, democratic safeguards (election of
officials, reduction
of salaries, free debate and discussion of competing positions,
etc.) in the unions and popular organizations. Often such
organizations are able to displace the party and union
bureaucracies and lead important successful day-to-day struggles
that develop the political and ideological self-confidence of
the workers. Even
in non-revolutionary periods, relatively small revolutionary
socialist groups play a crucial role in organizing these “rank
and file” currents and in educating the most radical workers
in Marxian theory and politics.
In revolutionary and pre-revolutionary conjunctures, the
effective fusion of revolutionary nuclei with the broad vanguard
of the class into a real revolutionary workers party could open
the possibility of socialist revolution. A mass revolutionary
party with significant roots in the workers’ movement can help
promote the formation and centralization of organs of working
class power (councils in the neighborhoods, workplaces,
schools), pose a practical alternative to the reformist
bureaucrats attempts to limit the struggles within limits
compatible with capitalist profitability and political power,
and lead a successful seizure of power.[20]
The questions remains, despite the evident inability of
the bureaucracies in the unions and reformist parties to
organize even the most elementary, defensive struggles against
the employers’ offensive and the capitalist austerity drive,
why have we not seen the emergence of truly mass revolutionary
parties since the 1920s? In
the late 1930s, Trotsky and his supporters in the Fourth
International believed that the second World War would lead to a
terminal crisis of bureaucratic rule in the USSR and a rapid
collapse of the Stalinist Communist parties in capitalist
Europe, opening the road to building new, mass revolutionary
workers’ organizations. Again in the late 1960s and early
1970s, with the beginning of the “long-wave” of economic
stagnation and the tumultuous rise of workers struggles across
the capitalist world, revolutionary socialists inside and
outside the Fourth International expected their relatively small
organizations to grow rapidly and become rooted in the insurgent
layers of the working class. Ernest Mandel was certainly not
immune to the enthusiasm of this period:
The
essential function of the period from 1968 to the present day
[c. 1977--CP] has been to allow the far Left to accumulate
sufficient forces to enter this revolutionary period with the
realistic possibility of winning over the majority of the
working class.[21]
The
revolutionary left’s optimism, often bordering on
triumphalism, was sorely disappointed as the wave of mass
strikes and pre-revolutionary upsurges of the early 1970s turned
into the uninterrupted retreat of the working class across the
industrialized world in the 1980s and early 1990s. As the
capitalist offensive proceeded with few challenges, most of the
generation of students and young workers radicalized in the late
1960s and 1970s abandoned revolutionary
politics, and the promising revolutionary organizations of the
earlier period stagnated or went into decline. It is only in the
past year, with the massive and generally successful public
sector workers strike in France, the anti-austerity strikes in
Canada, and the still fragmented industrial actions like the
Dayton autoworkers’ strike in the US, that we see the possible
beginnings of a new combativity on the part of the working
classes of advanced capitalism.
Mandel in the late 1970s offered some tentative
explanations for why the upsurge of the late 1960s and early
1970s had not transformed the European revolutionary left into
organizations of several tens of thousands of worker
revolutionaries. On
the one hand, he pointed to what he saw as a temporary
disorientation of the new “militant minority” that had
arisen in the European labor movement since 1968. The global
recession of 1974-75 and the beginnings of the employers’
offensive and austerity drive, coinciding with the defeat of the
Portuguese Revolution:
...caught
the working class unawares and unprepared... I mean the bulwark
of the working class, the vanguard, the organizing cadres, the
shop stewards—all those comrades who have been in the
forefront of the proletarian struggle in the past period. These
comrades were well seasoned and experienced in mounting
struggles to defend real wages against inflation, but they were
not at all prepared for a fight against massive unemployment.
This lack of experience was compounded by the total capitulation
of the bureaucracy—the Communist Party in Italy and Spain,
Social Democracy in most other countries—to the ideological
and political aspects of the bourgeois offensive on this
front...
However,
Mandel believed that this working class “has now been thrown
onto the defensive temporarily.”[22]
With nearly twenty years of hindsight, it is quite clear
that Mandel gravely underestimated the set-back suffered by the
European workers’ movement.
On the other hand, Mandel was aware of some of the
cumulative effects of the transformation of the Communist
parties into reformist organizations in the 1950s and 1960s. In
particular, Mandel noted:
...the
disappearance of an anti-capitalist tradition is a relatively
recent phenomenon, one which accompanied the definitive turn of
the Communist Parties in the industrially advanced countries at
the end of the Second world War, and especially at the end of
the Cold War. This sort of anti-capitalist education had
continued even during the Popular Front...Today, Social
democratic and Stalinist reformism are joining forces to keep
the working class a
prisoner of bourgeois and petty-bourgeois ideology. But any
vision of the class struggle that focused exclusively on this
aspect of reality would underestimate the almost structurally
anti-capitalist mainsprings inherent in the class struggle
during any phase of pronounced instability.[23]
Ultimately,
the obstacles to the construction of a mass revolutionary party
after 1968 were, in Mandel’s opinion, of an extremely
transitory character. In a relatively short period of time, be
believed revolutionary organizations would be able to sink roots
in the activist workers’ vanguard and establish small mass
parties with tens of thousands of members in the major
capitalist countries.
As the “temporary” set-back of the workers’
struggles in the late 1970s turned into the prolonged capitalist
offensive of the 1980s and 1990s, Mandel’s political
co-thinkers in the Fourth International began to look at more
long-term obstacles to the building of
mass revolutionary parties in the advanced capitalist
countries. In documents adapted at the last three World
Congresses of the Fourth International there has been a
recognition that the 1950s and 1960s saw a profound break in the
history of the workers’ vanguard. The notion that revolutionaries merely had to win over already militant,
anti-capitalist workers from the existing bureaucratized parties
has been replaced by a perspective that envisioned a gradual
recomposition of the workers’ vanguard through new mass
defensive struggles. In the words of a resolution of the most
recent World Congress of the Fourth International:
...a
new accumulation of mass experiences, partial victories and
radicalization of new generations is needed to bring together
all the conditions of a new leap forward in building vanguard
organizations that will be both revolutionary and
internationalist. The crisis of the revolutionary vanguard can
in fact no longer be posed in the terms of the 1930s. Today it
is not only a matter of changing a bankrupt leadership. The
necessary recomposition will not be limited to a change in the
balance of power within the organized workers’ movement as it
exists today. It has to go through the gradual reorganization of
the difference emancipation social movements internationally.
This will be a long process, which may be accelerated by certain
big events in the world class struggle.[24]
Mandel’s theory of bureaucracy, and his analysis of the
social and political transformation of the western Communist
parties actually holds the key to explaining the virtual
disappearance of a massive layer of radical and revolutionary
workers. Mandel, following Trotsky, saw the Seventh World
Congress of the Communist International as the turning point in
the evolution of the Stalinist parties in the advanced
capitalist countries.[25]
The “popular front” strategy transformed the
Communists parties politically and sociologically. Politically,
the CPs adapted the traditional strategy of reformism—the
defense of bourgeois democratic institutions as the best
guarantors of the “historic gains” of the labor movement.
Sociologically, the ‘popular front” led to the wholesale
integration of the Communist parties into the labor
bureaucracies in France, Italy and (in the late 1960s) Spain. In
other words, the CPs were transformed from parties of rank and
file worker militants who actively organized in their workplaces
against both the bureaucrats and the employers, into recruiting
grounds for trade union and party functionaries. Combined with
the effects of the long-wave of economic expansion in the 1950s
and 1960s, the social transformation of the Communist parties
all but destroyed the traditions of militancy, solidarity,
democracy and anti-capitalist radicalism defended by the mass
workers’ vanguard since the late nineteenth century. This new
situation poses new and difficult tasks for revolutionary
Marxists in the west. While continuing revolutionary socialist
propaganda and education aimed at recruiting and training
workers activists as Marxists, they must also play an active and
leading role in reorganizing
a workers’ vanguard, around a “class struggle”, but
not explicitly socialist, program of militancy, solidarity,
democracy and political independence. [26]
II.
THE BUREAUCRACY IN THE POST-CAPITALIST SOCIETIES
Mandel’s theory of the Stalinist bureaucracies in the
post-capitalist societies deepened Trotsky’s pathbreaking
Marxist analysis of the origins and contradictions of the
bureaucratic rule of the Soviet Union. [27]
The bulk of the Bolshevik leaders in the 1920s viewed the growth
of the full-time officialdom in the post-revolutionary party and
state, in Mandel’s words, “as a purely power-political,
institutional... administrative problem” because of their
“substitutionist concept of the party-worker relationship: the
dictatorship of the proletariat is exercised by the party under
the leadership of its Leninist Central Committee.”
In other words, most Russian revolutionaries saw the
problem as one of “bureaucratism”—inefficient
administration and bad-decision making by incompetent officials.
In 1923, Trotsky was the first Marxist to understand that:
“the
transformation of ...[the Soviet] bureaucracy into a specific
social layer with its own particular material interests. The
party apparatus defended its monopoly of political power as a
means of defending and extending its own material interests.[28]
For
Mandel, Trotsky’s understanding of the material
roots and character of the Stalinist officialdom enabled him to
develop both a rigorous Marxian analysis of the dynamics and
contradictions of the bureaucratized Soviet society, and a
consistent political strategy, based on the revolutionary
self-organization and self-activity of the workers, to oppose
bureaucratic rule.
Mandel and Trotsky’s theory of the bureaucratization of
post-capitalist societies begins from Marx’s assertion of the
necessity of a phase of transition between capitalism and
socialism.[29]
To move immediately after the global (no less than a merely
national) overthrow of capitalism (an economy of generalized
commodity production and growing inequalities within and between
societies), to socialism, (an economy of democratic planning by
the “freely associated producers” where social inequality
and the state are “withering away”) is impossible
because capitalism prevents the even and steady
development of labor productivity to its fullest potential.
While the application
of science and technology to the production process on a
global scale in the late twentieth century would allow all
humans’ basic needs to be met relatively quickly and
painlessly, this would require a:
restriction
of needs to the most elementary ones: men
would have to be content with eating just enough to appease
their hunger, dressing quietly, living in a rudimentary type of
dwelling, sending their children to schools of a quite
elementary kind and enjoying only a restricted health service.[30]
In order for the entirety of humanity to enjoy a standard
of living and, even more importantly,
a reduced working day that will allow them to develop their fullest
potential, eliminate economic inequalities and promote the
“withering away” of the state,
a further development of the global productive forces is
necessary. This, in turn, requires the preservation of certain
norms of “bourgeois distribution”—to each according to
their labor, rather
than their needs. The
wage form, money, markets for certain consumer goods, and a
state apparatus that ensures that all will work are necessary
features of a society in transition to socialism. While the
classical Marxist tradition believed that workers’ democracy
was possible and necessary to a successful transition, they also
recognized that the maintenance of the state and “bourgeois
norms of distribution” carried with it the possibility of the
development of new forms of social inequality and conflict.
However, revolutionary Marxists before the mid- 1920s believed
that a rapid victory of a world socialist revolution, especially
its spread to the most industrially advanced capitalist
societies, would greatly reduce these dangers.[31]
The actual development of the world revolution in the
twentieth century, the historic “stalemate in the
international class struggle”[32]
that developed after 1923, confronted the revolutionary Marxist
movement with a completely unexpected situation. Rather than
beginning the global transition to socialism in a number of
countries, including the more industrialized like Germany and
Italy; the revolution was isolated in the most economically
backward part of Europe, the former Russian empire. Russia’s
economic backwardness was compounded by the devastating effects
of the civil
war—the death of much of the generation of revolutionary
workers who had made the October revolution, extensive
destruction of the country’s meager industrial base and the
dispersal of the bulk of the industrial proletariat to the
countryside. The failure of the German and Italian revolutions,
for which the social-democratic bureaucracies bear major
responsibility, created a situation in Russia where all of the
inherent contradictions in a transitional society—between
socialized production and bourgeois distribution—were
intensified.
The absence of the two main preconditions for a
successful transition to socialism—material abundance and a
large and concentrated proletariat—created the environment for
the growth of the Soviet bureaucracy. A layer of full-time state
and party officials separate from the mass of workers emerged
first to administer the distribution of scarce goods and
services among the population. During the civil war, the number
of state and party officials began to grow, as the Soviets
requisitioned grain from the peasants to feed the urban workers
and Red Army, and attempted to organize the shrinking
state-owned industries for war production. The party and state
bureaucracy mushroomed in the 1920s under the New Economic
Policy, which allowed for the revival of commodity production
and circulation in both the cities and countryside. In the late
1920s and 1930s, the Soviet bureaucracy deepened its grip over
the state institutions and state owned means of production with
the disastrous collectivization of agriculture and the creation
of the “command economy.”
The bureaucracy, through its purge of the party and state
apparatus in the late 1930s, dispersed and disorganized all
opposition, particularly from the working class and peasantry,
and consolidated their political power and enormous material
privileges.[33]
Like Trotsky before him, Mandel emphasized the objective,
material sources of the bureaucratization of the Soviet Union.
On the one hand, the need for an agency, “above society”, to
distribute goods in a situation of extreme material scarcity
provided a fertile environment for the growth of the party-state
officialdom. On the other, the dispersal of the industrial
proletariat through unemployment undermined the activist social
base of Soviet democracy.[34]
However, both Mandel and Trotsky recognized that the
Bolsheviks’ made important subjective political errors that
contributed to the victory of the Stalinist bureaucracy,
particularly after the revolutionaries victory in the civil war.
Trotsky and Mandel argued that the decisions of the Tenth
Congress of the Communist Party in 1921-- the blanket
prohibition on all opposition parties from participation in the
Soviets and the ban on opposition factions within the ruling
party -- “hindered rather than promoted the self-activity of the
Russian workers.”[35]
These decisions undermined the ability of the Soviet
workers, even the most politically active party members, from
organizing themselves against the emerging bureaucracy, and gave
these bureaucracies a potent ideological weapons against any and
all opposition within and without the ruling party. As Trotsky
recognized in 1937:
The
prohibition of parties brought after it the prohibition of
factions. The prohibition of factions ended in a prohibition to
think otherwise than the infallible leaders. The
police-manufactured monolithism of the party resulted in a
bureaucratic impunity which as become the source of all kinds of
wantonness and corruption.[36]
In the last years of his life, Mandel forthrightly
confronted the presence of unmistakably substitutionist
elements in the politics of Lenin and Trotsky during the
“dark years” of 1920-1921.[37]
While clearly embracing Marcel Liebman’s
characterization of pre-revolutionary Bolshevism as a stridently
anti-substitutionist “libertarian Leninism,”[38]
Mandel revealed how the Bolshevik leaders transformed violations
of workers’ democracy necessitated by the civil war into political virtues. Specifically, Lenin and Trotsky argued that
temporary bans on opposition socialist parties, limitations of
peasant and bourgeois suffrage,
and empowering the Cheka
to arrest, try and execute accused counter-revolutionaries
without any political oversight were necessary
and desirable features of
proletarian rule. In
numerous writings, both Lenin and Trotsky defended a clearly
substitutionist conception of the relationship of the party and
the working class. In Terrorism and Communism (which Mandel correctly declared “his
worst book”[39])
and his polemics against the “Workers’ Opposition”,
Trotsky proclaimed that the working class was a “wavering
mass” incapable of exercising its rule directly and
democratically. In the same years, Lenin repeatedly described
the mass of workers as hopelessly divided, with sectors (the
“labor aristocracy’) corrupted by capital. In 1920-21, both
proclaimed the party as the only force—even against the wishes
and desires of the working class—capable of building
socialism. Mandel did the revolutionary Marxist movement a great
service by recognizing and rejecting
this aspect of our tradition.
As in the case of the labor bureaucracy in the capitalist
countries, the ruling officialdoms in the former Soviet Union
and the other bureaucratic societies developed their own,
substitutionist world-view and political practice. The
“dialectic of partial conquests” led the ruling
bureaucracies in the east to embrace their particular version of
“organizational fetishism”—the belief that the
preservation of existing state-party institutions took priority
over self-organization and self-activity of the working class.
Internally, the Stalinist and neo-Stalinist
bureaucrats’ substitutionism privileged the “leading role of
the party.” The
ruling Communist parties were the sole, legitimate
representatives of the working class. They alone could defend
the “historic interests” of the working class against all
enemies, including “dissidents” and “deviationists” from
within the ranks of the working class itself. The
substitutionist ideology of the ruling bureaucracies provided
ready made justifications for the brutal repression unleashed
against the working class during the Soviet purges of the 1930s,
the uprisings in East Germany, Poland and Hungary in the 1950s,
against the “Prague Spring” in 1968, the mass strikes in
Poland in 1971 and 1981, and the students and workers in
Tiananmen Square in 1989. For the bureaucratic regimes, only the
party, not the workers, were the ultimate guarantors of “true
interests” of the proletariat.[40]
Externally, the ruling bureaucracies’ sought to
subordinate the struggle of working people in other countries to
the “defense of socialism in one (choose your favorite)
country.” Mandel
extended Trotsky’s analysis of the disastrous results of
giving priority to the defense of some “socialist
fatherland” abroad over the actual struggles of the workers
and oppressed at home. The Communist parties in Germany in 1933,
France and Spain in 1936-37,
Greece after the second World War and in Indonesia in
1965 paid an extremely high price—massive repression and
hundreds of thousands of militants murdered—for placing the
diplomatic needs of the post-capitalist bureaucracies ahead of
the needs of the class struggle in their own countries.
Subservience to the ruling officialdoms in the east created the
conditions for the gradual transformation the French, Italian
and Spanish Communist parties into reformist parties; and led to
the collapse of much of the revolutionary left of the 1960s that
looked to the Maoist bureaucracy for political guidance.[41]
Ultimately, the post-capitalist bureaucracies were
incapable of consolidating a prosperous, attractive and stable
alternative to capitalism. One of Mandel’s major contributions
has been his elaboration of Trotsky’s insights into the limits
of bureaucratic central planning:
The
progressive role of the Soviet bureaucracy coincides with the
period devoted to introducing into the Soviet Union the most
important elements of capitalist technique... It is possible to
build gigantic factories according to a ready-made Western
pattern by bureaucratic command—although, to be sure, at
triple the normal cost. But the farther you go, the more the
economy runs into the problem of quality, which slips out of the
hands of a bureaucracy like a shadow... Under a nationalized
economy, quality demands a democracy of producers and consumers, freedom of
criticism and initiative—conditions incompatible with a
totalitarian regime of fear, lies and flattery.[42]
Mandel
theoretically refined and empirically documented this thesis
with extensive research.[43]
By substituting the party-state officialdom for the
democratic decisions of workers and consumers, the Stalinized
command economies were (and are in the case of China)
left without any mechanism for insuring the long-term and
continuous development of labor productivity. The
post-capitalist bureaucracies were capable of organizing extensive
growth, forcing millions of uprooted peasants to labor in plants
that reproduced the labor processes of the capitalist west,
producing an “ one time only” increase in labor
productivity. However, they floundered when faced with
organizing intensive
growth, the continuous replacement of labor with new
technologies and production of new items of consumption. The
bureaucracy lacked either the “whip of competition” that
ensures that each capitalist firm continuously reduces necessary
labor through mechanization, or the democratic control over
economic decisions by the “freely
associated producers and consumers” with an interest in
reducing their labor time and insuring quality items of
individual and collective consumption. As a result, the
bureaucratic economies were under no economic or political
compulsion to develop new technique or economize on the use of
resources. The result was that “a general lack of
responsibility, and indifference to the factory’s performance
is therefore a characteristic feature of the system and
threatens the USSR with stagnation and decline.”[44] The fate
of the bureaucratic command economies in Eastern Europe and the
ex-USSR tragically confirmed Mandel and Trotsky’s theses.
Unlike Trotsky, who confined himself to a general call
for the restoration of soviet democracy through an
anti-bureaucratic workers’ revolution, Mandel presented a
detailed model of democratic centralist economic planning. A
global “self-administered” economy would be founded upon
democratic councils of producers and consumers. The officials of
these councils would be elected by the entire adult population,
would be subject to immediate recall and would be paid the
average salary of a skilled worker. These democratic
institutions of workers’ power, created through
anti-capitalist revolutions in the west and anti-bureaucratic
revolutions in the east, would be articulated at the
international, national, industrial and office, factory or
neighborhood level, where:
Decisions
should be taken at the level at which they can most easily be
implemented. And they should be taken at the level where the
greatest percentage of people actually affected by them can be
involved in the decision-making process.[45]
Put
simply, international and national bodies would be empowered to
draw up the basic outlines of the economic plan, while
industrial, regional or plant-office bodies would decide how to
implement their particular parts of the plan in consultation
with those who will consume their product.[46]
In order for democratic “self-administration” to be
effective, the working class must be able to express their needs
and desires in the planning process and there must be mechanisms
for the correction of social and economic miscalculations.
According to Mandel, political
pluralism is required to allow the working class, in all its
heterogeneity, to effectively control the planning process.
Without the right of all political currents (including
ideologically pro-capitalist tendencies) to organize political
parties, have access (in proportion to their numbers) to the
media and to organize demonstrations and other non-violent
actions to advance their particular view point, central planning
will not be able to utilize productive resources efficiently and
raise the productivity of labor. Mandel also recognized that formally democratic institutions
and the rigorous guarantee of political rights for all sectors
of the population, while necessary
conditions for democratic socialist rule, are not sufficient.
There are also crucial social and economic conditions, most
importantly the radical reduction of working time for the mass
of the population so that all “have the time to administer the
affairs of their workplace or neighborhood.”[47]
Such a reduction of the working day would allow most of
humanity to spend 3-4 hours a day in the production of goods or
provision of services and another 3-4 hours a day in the work of
social self-administration. In order to abolish the division
between mental and manual labor, the basis of bureaucracy, there
must be generalized access to education, culture and literacy,
which assumes a high level of material abundance and labor
productivity . This,
Mandel asserted, will only be possible when not only
bureaucratic rule has been replaced in the east, but capitalism
has been overthrown in a number of advanced industrial societies
and their vast productive potential freed.[48]
Mandel, like Marx and Trotsky before him, recognized that
commodity production and circulation, the market, would survive
for a considerable period after the overthrow of capitalism on a
world scale. Mandel
agreed with Alec Nove, the most sophisticated theorist of
“market socialism” that “the radical suppression of
residual market relations” in any of the post-capitalist
societies was not “presently desirable or practical.”
In fact, Mandel saw elements of Nove’s model of
“feasible socialism” as similar to his own conception of the
combination of market and plan in a democratically ruled society
in transition to socialism.[49]
Mandel’s disagreement with the “market socialists”
was their claim that commodity production was a permanent and
unalterable feature of economic life. For Nove, the complexity
of economic decisions in an industrialized economy and the
“unlimited wants” of human beings made the abolition of
scarcity, the foundation of commodity production, impossible.
The withering away of the market was possible for two
reasons according to Mandel. First,
a system of “articulated self-management” could
allocate most of the thousands of decisions necessary to a
planned economy to different democratically organized bodies,
overcoming the problem of “too many decisions.”
Second, it
was possible to envision a “saturation of demand” for goods
and services once basic material needs were satisfied. Mandel
rejected the simplistic notion of “human nature’ that
underlies both neo-classical economics and the theories of
“market socialism”:
The
continual accumulation of more and more goods... is by no means
a universal or even predominant feature of human behavior. The
development of talents and inclinations for their own sake; the
protection of health and life; care for children; the
development of rich social relations as a prerequisite of mental
stability and happiness—all these become major motivations
once basic material needs have been satisfied. One has only to
look at how the upper reaches of the bourgeoisie conduct
themselves with regard to food, clothing, housing, furniture or
‘cultural goods’ to note that for those who already
‘live under communism’, rational consumption takes
the place of a restless pursuit of more.[50]
Mandel, responding to the rise of the environmental
movements of the last twenty five years, incorporated a detailed
discussion of the relationship of different forms of social and
economic organization to the natural environment. Mandel
addressed two objections to the Marxian vision of socialism
raised in the “Green” analysis of the rape of the
environment in both capitalist and bureaucratic economies.
Various “Green” theorists argue that the Marxian vision of a
future society based upon the abolition of material scarcity
would place an unbearable strain on the physical resources of
the planet and lead to an ecological disaster. Mandel pointed to
the scale of socially wasted resources under both capitalism and
the bureaucratic command economies. The immediate abolition of
the arms industry alone would free up tremendous resources for
socially useful production (based upon renewable energy sources,
environmentally safe technologies, etc.) that could provide an
adequate standard of living for the bulk of the worlds’
population without thrusting new demands upon the finite
capacities of the planet. As the basic, material needs for
physical security and gratification (food, clothing, shelter,
medical care, education) are met, priority could be given to
meeting the non-material needs for “self-actualization”
(cultural, political, intellectual and personal development),
needs whose satisfaction do not require utilizing finite natural
resources.
The second “Green” critique of Marxism, based upon
the experience of ecological disaster in the former USSR and
eastern Europe, claims that centrally planned economies are no
more ecologically friendly than market-capitalist economies. For
Mandel, the destruction of the environment in the east flowed
from the same bureaucratic mismanagement that gave rise to
systematic waste of labor power and other resources. In other
words, the absence of any democratic accountability on the parts
of central planners and industrial managers allowed them to
systematically befoul the physical environment in the east. By
contrast, a democratically planned economy has the potential to
avoid the ecological disasters that characterize both capitalism
and the bureaucratic command economies. Workers and consumers
actively involved in formulating and implementing an economic
plan have a compelling interest in developing labor processes
that will neither destroy the health of those directly involved
in production, nor befoul the air and water that all must breath
and drink. In
addition, the possibility of democratic “self-correction”
would minimize environmental damage that might ensue from
workers’ attempting to raise their standard of living without
consideration of its effects on future generations.[51]
Mandel’s elaboration and extension of Trotsky’s
theory of the post-capitalist bureaucracies not only provides an
powerful alternative to liberal, social-democratic and Stalinist
theories of bureaucracy, but to other Marxian theories as well.
In particular, Mandel has produced an extensive critique of the
theory that the former USSR, eastern Europe and China were
“state capitalist” social formations.[52]
The notion that economies where the main means of
production are allocated according to conscious planning
decisions, however bureaucratically mismanaged, and not
according to differential profit rates and prices of production;
where labor-power is no longer a commodity and a state monopoly
of foreign trade mediates the effects of global capitalist
competition on the planned economy are capitalist is
theoretically and empirically untenable. This theory, as Mandel
pointed out numerous times, does violence both to the Marxian
theory of capitalist accumulation and the empirical reality of
the bureaucratic economies.[53]
Mandel’s critique of the other major alternative
Marxian theory of the bureaucratic regimes, the theory of
“bureaucratic collectivism”, is not as rigorous as his
dissection of the theory of “state-capitalism.” For Mandel, like Trotsky, the bureaucracy in the
post-capitalist societies is a caste,
a social layer that, unlike a social class, plays no
necessary role in social production. The ‘parasitic’
relationship between the bureaucracy and the planned economy
deprives these post-capitalist societies of the social coherence
of an established mode of production. Since the late 1930s,
various Marxist critics of Stalinism have challenged this
theory, arguing that the bureaucracy was a new exploiting class
that organized a new, post-capitalist mode of production in the
ex-USSR and the eastern bloc countries.[54]
The theory of “bureaucratic collectivism” has been
held by a wide variety of revolutionary socialists, including
many prominent anti-bureaucratic activists in the former eastern
bloc.[55]
Its theoretical attraction is not surprising. On the one
hand, it avoids the problems of the theory of “state
capitalism.” On
the other it avoids the complexities and ambiguities of Mandel
and Trotsky’s theory of a ‘transitional society’ by
situating the bureaucracy and the command economy in the
familiar Marxian categories of class and mode of production.
Mandel offers two different criticisms of the theory of
bureaucratic collectivism. The first and, in our opinion, the
weaker response points to the survival of commodity production
and circulation in the bureaucratic economies. The survival of
the wage form, the impact of the world market, etc. are features
of any transitional
society, and run counter to the logic of planning. Thus, these
economies are:
hybrid
combination
of an allocative and a commodity-producing economy, in which the
law of value operates but does not hold sway. And this influence
of the law of value ultimately sets immovable limits to bureaucratic despotism. This is
what theorists of ‘bureaucratic collectivism’...fail to
see... For a ‘new’,
‘bureaucratic’ non-capitalist mode of production to emerge,
the Soviet bureaucracy would have to have liberated itself once
and for all from the influence of the law of value. [56]
This line of argument is open to several important
criticisms. First, Mandel and Trotsky’s notion that the
bureaucracy’s privileges
and power are derived primarily from the survival of
“bourgeois norms of distribution”
is problematic. Much of the bureaucracy’s substantially
higher standard of living compared to the working class was not
derived from their superior incomes and market access to
commodities. It was instead based upon their political power,
derived from their command of the state apparatus and the state
owned means of production, to gain preferential non-market,
non-commodity access to consumer goods through special
stores and “jumping the queue” for relatively scarce
consumer goods like cars, housing, etc.
Second, and more importantly, there have been numerous
societies where non-capitalist modes of production coexisted
with quite extensive commodity circulation and where “the
privileges of the privileges of the dominant classes... are
mainly confined to the realm of private consumption, [and] they
have no long-term interest in a sustained increase in
productivity.”[57]
European feudalism, slavery in both classical antiquity
and the so-called “new world”, and the various “Asiatic”
societies all allowed for, and in some cases promoted extensive
commodity production, although not the generalized commodity
production possible only under capitalism. These same modes of
production were dominated by exploiting classes whose privilege
were confined to private consumption, and who were unable to
organize the labor process of their direct producers in a manner
that allowed for sustained increases in productivity. In fact,
it is only under capitalism that the ruling class’ privileges
extend to real possession of the means of production—the ability to organize
the labor process. Thus, the bourgeoisie is the first ruling
class in world history to be both capable of, and compelled to
continually raise the productivity of labor through
mechanization.[58]
The introduction of “market mechanisms” into the
bureaucratic command economies during the past twenty-five years
has demonstrated the possibility of combining “market” and
“plan” without undermining bureaucratic privilege and power.
The ruling officialdom in Yugoslavia, Poland, Hungary, China and
the former USSR all introduced “market reforms” at different
points in the last forty years in attempts to overcome the
chronic stagnation of labor productivity in the eastern bloc. As
we know, these reforms were singularly ineffective in either
stimulating intensive economic development or lessening
bureaucratic despotism. If anything, market mechanisms enriched
the bureaucracy and sharpened its antagonism with the working
class and peasantry without forcing productive units to
introduce new labor processes or use materials more efficiently.[59]
In sum, while the combination of planning and commodity
production is a necessary
feature of every society in transition from capitalism to
socialism, the combination of plan and market is not a sufficient
basis for rejecting the notion that a new mode of production
developed in the former USSR, eastern Europe and China.
Mandel’s second, and stronger critique of the
bureaucracy as a “new ruling class” points to the profound
contradiction between bureaucratic power and the logic of
effective economic planning. [60]
First, the bureaucracy has a “parasitic” relationship
to economic planning—it is theoretically unnecessary to a
planned economy. The working class could quite as easily
organize a planned economy without a privileged layer of
officials ,although, at least initially, not without specialists
and technicians. By comparison, one cannot conceive of an
economy of generalized commodity production without capitalists
and workers.
Second, the bureaucracy’s attempt to enrich itself
undermines the effectivity of the planning process. At every
level of the command economy, bureaucrats systematically hide
resources, whether labor power, raw material or machinery, in
order to meet production targets and obtain bonuses in the forms
of cash or access to better housing, vacations and the like.
Bureaucratic secrecy makes effective economic planning
impossible. Without realistic information about resources and
productive capacity it is impossible to set realistic production
targets. By contrast, the bourgeoisie’s efforts to enrich
itself deepens the
conditions of capitalist competition as each capitalist attempts
to undercut all others and increase their market share by
lowering costs. The individual self-interest of the capitalist coincides
with the operation of the law of value, but the individual
self-interest of the bureaucrat runs
counter to the logic of economic planning.
Finally, the contradictions between the privileges of the
bureaucracy and the logic of planning deprives the bureaucratic
economies of any internally generated dynamic of crisis and recovery. While the
bureaucracy’s privilege undermines the effectivity of
planning, leading to declining rates of growth in the 1970s and
1980s, there was no mechanism internal to the bureaucratic
economy that could resolve the crisis. Only a profound shift in
the relationship of social forces politically, either a
workers’ anti-bureaucratic revolution or capitalist
restoration, could establish the conditions for renewed growth.
Capitalism’s inherent drive to replace human labor generates
declining profit rates and periodic “long-waves” of economic
crisis. However, capitalism generates its own solution to these
prolonged crises. The massive destruction of inefficient
capitals and “redundant” labor during an economic collapse
restores the conditions of profitable accumulation and sparks a
new “long-wave” of expansion.[61]
Thus, there are no “terminal crises” of capitalism.
The rule of capital, like the feudal aristocracy and other
ruling classes rooted in modes of production, must be overthrown. The strongest historical validation of Trotsky and
Mandel’s thesis that the former USSR and
eastern European regimes were not rooted in a new mode of
production was the rapidity with which they collapsed in
1989-1991. Bureaucratic rule in these societies was not
overthrown by either the working class or imperialism, but imploded
as a result of chronic economic stagnation. Not surprisingly,
the social formations that emerged in eastern Europe and the
former Soviet Union have yet to make a successful transition to
capitalism.
While Mandel and Trotsky’s theory of the
“transitional” character of the post-capitalist societies
remains convincing, their the claim that these regimes were
“bureaucratized” forms of the proletarian dictatorship is
open to question.[62] Through
the early years of the Russian revolution, revolutionary
Marxists generally equated the workers’ state with highly
democratic forms of popular participation and power, in
particular with the Paris Commune of 1871 and the workers’,
soldiers and peasants councils that had arisen in Russia,
Germany, Hungary and Italy between 1917 and 1921.[63]
The defeat of the central and western European
revolutions and the devastation of the civil war undermined the
viability of the Russian soviets as organs of popular power. For
Lenin and Trotsky, the working class character of the Russian
state was preserved in the Community party, which organized the
most active and radical workers.
However, the “rule of the party” proved an inadequate
basis for preserving even an indirect form of workers’
self-government. The decline of party democracy after the 1921
ban on factions and the consolidation of the party-state
bureaucracy in the late 1920s transformed the Soviet Communist
party into the political instrument of the Stalinist
officialdom.
By the late 1930s, Trotsky argued that the Soviet Union
remained a workers’ state, despite the “political
expropriation” of the working class, because the bureaucracy
continued to defend the social and economic “conquests of the
October Revolution”—nationalized property, central planning
and a state monopoly on foreign trade. The Soviet regime was a
form of “bonapartism”, similar to both feudal Absolutism,
where the aristocracy ceded power to a royal bureaucracy that
preserved feudalism, and fascism, where the bourgeoisie ceded
power to a petty-bourgeoisie that safeguarded the conditions of
capitalist accumulation. Thus, the mainstream of the Trotskyist
movement, including Mandel, saw the USSR, and later eastern
Europe, China and Vietnam, as “bureaucratized workers’
states” where the working class ruled but did not govern. [64]
There are compelling theoretical reasons for maintaining
the theory of the “bureaucratized workers’ states.”
Most importantly, the traditional Trotskyist conception
is consistent with the fundamental Marxian axiom that every
society torn by social conflicts, no matter how unstable and
transitional, are ruled by a single social class. As Perry
Anderson argued, Trotsky’s interpretation of Stalinism:
...provides
a theory of the phenomenon of Stalinism in a long historical
temporality, congruent with the fundamental categories of
classical Marxism. At every point in his account of the nature
of the Soviet bureaucracy, Trotsky sought to situate it in the
logic of successive modes of production and transitions between
them, with corresponding class powers and political regimes,
that he inherited from Marx, Engels or Lenin...Because he could
think of the emergence and consolidation of Stalinism in a
historical time-span of this epochal character, he avoided the
explanations of hasty journalism and improvised confections of
new classes or modes of production, unanchored in historical
materialism, which marked the reaction of many of his
contemporaries.[65]
These strengths, however, conceal profound problems with
the concept of a “workers’ state” where the workers rule,
but do not govern. The analogy with feudal absolutism and
capitalist dictatorships tends to obscure the differentia
specifica of the transition to socialism. First, neither the
feudal nor capitalist modes of production emerged from the
struggles of classes self-consciously attempting to create new
forms of society. Instead, feudalism and capitalism arose out of
the struggles of already propertied classes to consolidate and
extend their class domination. Socialism, by contrast, is the
first form of society created in a conscious struggle by a propertyless
social class, the working class. Further, both feudalism and
capitalism are reproduced through a “blind economic logic”
that operates “behind the back” of both the economically
dominant classes and the direct producers. The feudal
aristocracy and the bourgeoisie can remain socially dominant
without directly dominating the state. Socialism is the first
form of society based on conscious and deliberate planning of
economic development. These profound differences between
socialism and all previous forms of social labor led Mandel to
argue in his last major work:
There
is no way in which the working class can rule without governing.
It
has to exercise power simultaneously within enterprise and
branch, municipality and region, as well as at the aggregate
levels of the state and the national economy; if it is to
‘rule’ in any real and direct sense of the word: to take the
key decisions about economic, social, and cultural priorities in
the allocation of scarce resources. Thus, the functional
division of the proletariat, between those who ‘professionally
exercise power’ and the mass of the class, sets in motion a
social process which suppresses the direct collective rule of
the class as such.[66]
Here
Mandel provided compelling reasons for rejecting the analogy
between absolutism, fascism and bureaucratic rule that he and
Trotsky upon which they had based their notion of a
“bureaucratized workers’ state.”
In other writings, Mandel attempted to defend the
“bureaucratized workers’ state” theory by arguing that the
Stalinist bureaucracy was a privileged layer of the working
class which had usurped power from the rest of the class. First,
he claimed that the bureaucracy’s derived most of its
privileges in the form of wages:
...the
bureaucracy, since it does not own the means of production,
participates in distribution of the national income exclusively
as a function of remuneration for its labor-power. This entails
many privileges, but it is a form of remuneration that does not
differ qualitatively from remuneration in the form of a salary.[67]
This
claim is open to two criticisms. First, as we have already seen,
the bureaucracy secures much of its greater levels of
consumption through non-wage,
non-market access to consumer goods. The officialdom’s
access to special stores, dachas
and the like derives from their political power—their
domination of the state apparatus and control over state owned
means of production. Second, the wage form, while a necessary characteristic of the working class is not
sufficient to define a social group as part of the
proletariat. In the capitalist social formations, top and middle
level corporate executives receive salaries. Even when these
executives do not own stock (although most do), they are part of
the capitalist class because they command the labor-power of
others and dispose of the means of production. Similarly, it can
be argued that a much larger layer of wage-earners—low level
supervisors, technicians and professionals—are not part of the
working class in advanced capitalism. Many contemporary Marxists
view these groups as forming a new middle class, produced by of
the concentration and centralization of capital and the
systematic application of science to production under
capitalism.[68]
Mandel also argued that the post-capitalist bureaucracy
was a layer of the working class because of the ease by which
individual workers moved into the bureaucracy.
For
it is absolutely certain that a good number of today’s
bureaucrats, in this broad and real sense of the term, are not
merely the sons and daughters of workers but even former workers
themselves... The particular structure of society in the Soviet
Union enables the bureaucracy to absorb the sons and daughters
of workers, and even workers themselves, into the apparatus. Not
into the summits of the apparatus, but into positions much
higher than those of the so-called middle classes in the
advanced capitalist countries.[69]
Granting
much higher, but clearly slowing, rates of upward social
mobility between the working class and the bureaucracy in the
east than between the working and capitalist classes in the
west,[70]
this argument remains theoretically unconvincing. From a Marxian
perspective, classes are defined by their objective relationship
to social production, not the social origins of their members.
Put simply, contemporary capitalist societies could experience a
significant increase in social mobility—the wholesale
proletarianization of the
bourgeoisie and the bourgeoisification of a small minority of
the working class—without altering the structural relationship
between capital and wage labor. The fact that many, or even
most, post-capitalist bureaucrats came from the working class
did not make the officialdom part of the proletariat.
Our discussion of the post-capitalist bureaucracy leaves
us in a difficult theoretical position. On the one hand, there
is little theoretical or empirical basis for the notion that the
bureaucracy is a new social class based in a new mode of
production. The
post-capitalist command economies were transitional societies,
whose progress toward socialism was blocked by the rule of an
officialdom whose power and privileges made effective economic
planning impossible. On the other hand, it is extremely
difficult to argue that the bureaucratic regimes were
“deformed” forms of the proletarian dictatorship. The
working class in the east neither ruled nor governed, and the
bureaucracy was not a “layer” of the working class. This
leaves us unable to identify what class ruled the former USSR,
eastern Europe and China. At best, we can say that these
societies were “historical abortions”, the product of the
“global stalemate of the class struggle” in the twentieth
century. They were highly unstable, transitional societies
governed by bureaucracies, who excluded the working classes from
any real or formal social and political power, but were not
themselves ruling classes. Their rapid implosion in 1989-1991
demonstrated their profound instability and the bureaucracy’s
thoroughly “parasitic” character. This is the best
understanding we as Marxists can have of these societies based
upon our experience of their actual historical evolution.
Further theoretical clarification would require the emergence of
new bureaucratized transitional societies, which would provide
us with additional “raw material” for our theory. For that
reason, we have reason to hope this is a theoretical issue that
will never be settled decisively.
III.
CONCLUSION: THE NECESSITY OF WORKING CLASS SELF-EMANCIPATION AND
WORKERS’ DEMOCRACY
Mandel, working from the foundation provided by Luxemburg
and Trotsky, has provided us with the most theoretically
rigorous and empirically well-founded Marxian discussion of
bureaucracy to date. Mandel’s analysis of the labor
officialdom under capitalism and the ruling bureaucracy in the
post-capitalist social formations is a powerful alternative to
the liberal, social-democratic and Stalinist theories that claim
that the rule of a full-time corps of non-propertied officials
is an unavoidable feature of modern society. Rather than an
unavoidable development in human history, bureaucracy is the
product of specific and historically transitory social relations
and material forces of production.
Mandel does much more than demonstrate that democratic
self-organization of the working class in both capitalist and
post-capitalist societies is possible.
His theory of bureaucracy, together with his investigations into
the dynamics of capitalist accumulation in the twentieth
century, points to the necessity
of working class self-emancipation as the only basis for human
liberation and survival. The notions that the labor bureaucrats
can defend the gains of workers under capitalism or that the
ruling bureaucracies can construct a viable alternative to
capitalism has proven to be thoroughly utopian.
The material position and self-interest of the reformist
bureaucracies in the west have led them to disorganize and
demobilize the working class and surrender, practically without
a struggle, most of the hard fought for gains of the past half
century. The material position and self-interest of the ruling
bureaucracies in the east have led them to undermine the
planning process and waste precious human and natural resources.
In short, the failure of bureaucratic strategies for gradually
reforming capitalism or building an authoritarian alternative to
it have necessarily floundered on the social
position of the bureaucracies in both the capitalist and
post-capitalist social formations.
Mandel’s theory of bureaucracy is one of the central scientific
foundations of our revolutionary socialist political project in
the late twentieth century. Our contention that the
self-activity and self-organization of the working class
provides the only possible
basis for stemming the current capitalist
offensive, overthrowing of the rule of capital and
constructing an alternative collectivist social order
flows directly from Mandel’s theory of the social-democratic
and Stalinist bureaucracies. Not goodwill, democratic idealism
or a commitment to an egalitarian morality alone, but a scientific
understanding of the role of the officialdom of the workers’
movement and post-capitalist societies leads us to defend
working class self-emancipation as the only practical alternative to capitalist barbarism.
[1]Max
Weber, Economy and
Society: An Outline of Interpretive Sociology, Volume 2
(Berkeley: University of California Press, 1979), Chapter
XI.
[2]Robert
Michels, Political
Parties: A Sociological Study of the Oligarchical Tendencies
of Modern Democracy (New York: The Free Press, 1962;
originally published in German in 1911).
[3]For
our purposes, the three most important works are: Marxist
Economic Theory, Volume II (New York: Monthly Review
Press, 1970), Chapter 15; "What is the
Bureaucracy?" in T. Ali (ed.), The
Stalinist Legacy: Its Impact on 20th Century World Politics
(Harmondsworth: Penguin Books, 1984); Power
and Money: A Marxist Theory of Bureaucracy (London:
Verso, 1992).
[4]"What
is the Bureaucracy?" 75.
[5]Lenin's
theory of the "labor aristocracy"
flows from his theory of "monopoly
capitalism."
See: V.I. Lenin, Imperialism:
The Highest Stage of Capitalism: A Popular Outline",
Chapter VIII in Lenin: Selected Works, Volume 1 (Moscow: Progress Publishers, 1970).
[6]Mandel's
critique of Lenin's theory of the "labor
aristocracy" is found in "What is the
Bureaucracy?" 75-76. Mandel's thinking on the roots of
wage differentials between workers in the "third
world" and the industrialized capitalist societies
underwent considerable evolution. In Marxist
Economic Theory [II, 453-459], Mandel argued that the
low wages of workers in the underdeveloped capitalist
countries accounts for the low organic composition of
capital and low rate of exploitation in these societies. In Late
Capitalism [(London: New Left Books, 1975), 359-364]
Mandel argued, correctly in our opinion, that the uneven
development of fixed capital and labor productivity is the
cause of global wage differentials.
More recent
discussions of the theory of the "labor
aristocracy" and wage differentials have rejected the
idea that "monopoly" or "oligopoly"--
the absence or limitation of competition-- is the root of
wage differentials. Instead, wage differentials are the
result of real capitalist competition, which necessarily
gives rise to different degrees of capital intensity within
and between branches of production. See: Samuel Freidman,
"The Theory of the Labor Aristocracy" Against
the Current (Old Series) 2,3 (Fall 1983); Samuel
Freidman, "Structure, Process and the Labor
Market," in William Darity, Jr., Labor
Economics: Modern Views (Hingham, MA: Kluwer-Nijhoff,
1983); and Howard Botwinick, Persistent Inequalities: Wage Disparity Under Capitalist Competition
(Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1993).
[7]"What
is the Bureaucracy?" 72-75.
[8]Luxemburg's
most important work in this regard was The
Mass Strike, The Political Party and the Trade Unions
(New York: Harper & Row, 1971).
[9]Mandel’s
theory of class consciousness is presented at length in
"The Leninist Theory of Organization: Its Relevance for
Today" in S. Bloom (ed.), Revolutionary
Marxist and Social Reality in the 20th Century: Collected
Essays of Ernest Mandel (Atlantic Highlands, NJ:
Humanities Press International, Inc. 1994), 80-91. A similar
argument is made in J. Brenner and R. Brenner, “Reagan,
the Right and the Working Class,” Against
the Current, (Old Series) 1,2 (Winter 1981), 29-35.
[10]"Leninist
Theory of Organization," 85.
[11]Power
and Money,
59-60.
[12]Clearly,
the labor bureaucracy is not monolithic. Mass struggles have
led to splits among the leaders of the unions and reformist
parties in which a wing of the officialdom attempts to take
leadership of a wave of working class struggles. However,
this realignment of a sector of the officialdom is generally
a response to independent organization and initiatives
“from below” (rank and file currents in the unions,
etc.) often led by radicals and revolutionaries. The
“rebel” bureaucrats attempt to intervene in these
struggle to contain them within boundaries of reformist
politics. This was clearly the case with John L. Lewis’
role in the emergence of mass industrial unionism in the US
during the 1930s. It may also have been the likely
background to the role of Carl Legien and other
social-democratic union officials in arming and mobilizing
German workers to defeat the Kapp Putsch in 1920. On the US
case see: A. Preis, Labor’s
Giant Step: Twenty Years of the CIO (New York:
Pathfinder Press, 1964), Part I; M. Davis, “The Barren
Marriage of American Labor and the Democrats,” New
Left Review 124 (November-December 1980), 46-54. On the
German case see: C. Harmon, The
Lost Revolution Germany 1918 to 1923 (London: Bookmarks,
1982) , Chapter 8.
[13]Power
and Money,
235 (emphasis in the original).
[14]We
are using "utopian" in the same sense that Marx
and Engels used it in relationship to the pre-Marxian
socialists, and Trotsky used it in relationship to the
Stalinist notion of "socialism in one country": a
strategy for social change that is not based on a realistic,
scientific
understanding of the dynamics of the capitalist mode of
production and the class struggle.
Mandel did
recognize there was a positive aspect to
"utopianism": the ability to imagine a better,
more democratic, egalitarian and collectivist social order
as a spur to revolutionary struggle. See Power
and Money, 232-235. See also Michael Lowy, On
Changing the World: Essays in Political Philosophy from Karl
Marx to Walter Benjamin (Atlantic Highlands, NJ:
Humanities Press, 1993).
[15]On
the social-democratization of the west European Communist
Parties, see Mandel, From
Stalinism to Eurocommunism:
The Bitter Fruits of 'Socialism in One Country" (London: New Left Books, 1977), Chapter 1.
[16]
See F. Claudin, The
Communist Movement: From Comintern to Cominform , Volume
I (New York: Monthly Review Press, 1975).
[17]Power
and Money,
236.
[18]Mandel
discusses this dynamic in detail in "The PCI and
Austerity" in From
Stalinism to Eurocommunism, 125-149. For a similar
analysis of the contradictions of reformism, see Robert
Brenner, "The Paradox of Reformism," Against
the Current 43 (March-April 1993).
[19]"The
Leninist Theory of Organization."
[20]One
of the best presentations of this strategy, despite its
grossly over-optimistic estimation of the short and medium
term possibility of revolution in western Europe in the late
1970s is Mandel, "Socialist Strategy in the West,"
in Revolutionary
Marxism Today (London:
New Left Books, 1977), Chapter 1.
[21]"Socialist
Strategy in the West," 42.
[22]"Socialist
Strategy in the West," 48-49.
[23]"Socialist
Strategy in the West," 61.
[24]"Building
the Fourth International Today," Documents
of the 14th World Congress of the fourth International,
Special Issue, International
Viewpoint (Spring 1996), 58.
[25]From
Stalinism to Eurocommunism,
17-22.
[26]This
argument is presented in much greater detail in C. Post and
K.A. Wainer, Socialist
Organization Today (Detroit, MI: Solidarity Pamphlet,
forthcoming 1996).
[27]The
most complete statement of Trotsky's mature analysis of the
Soviet bureaucracy is The
Revolution Betrayed: What
is the Soviet Union and Where Is It Going? (New York:
Pathfinder Press, 1977; originally published 1937). For an
excellent overview of the development of Trotsky's theory of
the Soviet bureaucracy, see Perry Anderson, "Trotsky's
Interpretation of Stalinism," in Ali (ed.) The Stalinist Legacy, 118-128.
[28]Mandel,
Trotsky As Alternative
(London: Verso Books, 1995), 41.
[29]Marx's
discussion of the necessity of a transitional phase between
capitalism and socialism is contained in his brief
"marginal notes" on the 1875 program of the German
Workers' Party, Critique
of the Gotha Programme (New York: International
Publishers, 1938). Trotsky's more elaborate discussion of
the transition is found in Revolution
Betrayed, Chapter III. For Mandel's contribution to this
discussion, see: Marxist
Economy Theory, II, Chapter 16.
[30]Mandel,
Marxist Economic Theory, II, 608. (emphasis
in the original)
[31]On
the near unanimity of the leadership of the Communist
International, prior to 1923, on the impossibility of
constructing "socialism in one country," see
Trotsky, "The Draft Program of the communist
International-- A criticism of Fundamentals" in The
Third International After Lenin (New
York: Pathfinder Press, 1970; first published 1936), 3-73.
[32]Mandel,
Trotsky as Alternative,
47.
[33]Mandel's
analysis of the material roots and development of the Soviet
bureaucracy in Power
and Money, Chapter 2 and Trotsky
as Alternative, Chapter 3, closely follows that of
Trotsky in The
Revolution Betrayed, Chapters II, IV, V. Mandel provided
a very powerful reply to various social-democrats and former
Stalinists who claim that Stalin's merely implemented
Trotsky's economic proposals, albeit in a "barbaric
form", in the late 1920s and 1930s. In Trotsky
as Alternative, Chapter 4, Mandel demonstrated that
Trotsky continued, until his death in 1940, to advocate a
democratically controlled economy that combined a dominant
state-owned, planned sector with market mechanisms.
[34]Samuel
Farber [Before
Stalinism: The Rise and Fall of Soviet Democracy
(London: Verso Books, 1990)] despite many important
insights, tends to underestimate the weight of these
material factors as he highlights the Bolshevik's
mainstream's subjective underestimation of democratic
institutions and rights. For a good discussion of the
strengths and weaknesses of Farber's work, see David Mandel, "The Rise & Fall of Soviet
Democracy," Against
the Current 37 (March-April 1992),
48-49.
[35]Mandel,
Trotsky as Alternative,
82.
[36]Trotsky,
The Revolution
Betrayed, 104-105. Trotsky's most lengthy discussion of
these issues is Stalinism
v. Bolshevism (New York: Pathfinder Press, 1974,
originally published 1939). Mandel presents these points at
length in several works: "What is Bureaucracy?"
83-85; Power and Money,
117-118; Trotsky As
Alternative, pp. 81-82, 84-86.
[37]Power
and Money,
118-125; Trotsky As
Alternative, 83-84.
[38]Marcel
Liebman, Leninism
Under Lenin (London:
Merlin Press, 1975). See also Paul LeBlanc, Lenin
and the Revolutionary Party (Atlantic Highlands, NJ:
Humanities Press, 1993).
[39]Trotsky
As Alternative,
p. 83.
[40]Mandel,
Power and Money,
104-109.
[41]See
From Stalinism to
Eurocommunism and Revolutionary
Marxism Today, passim
for Mandel's discussions of the disastrous effects of
"socialism in one country" on the world labor
movement.
[42]Trotsky,
The Revolution
Betrayed, 275-276.
[43]Marxist
Economic Theory,
II, Chapter 15; Beyond
Perestroika: The Future of Gorbachev's USSR (London:
Verso, 1989 and 1991); Power
and Money, Chapter 1.
[44]Power
and Money,
42. One can see
similar patterns of wasted resources and low-quality to
consumers in the services provided by the capitalist state
(health care, postal-telecommunications, transport, etc.)
Again, the absence of either the “whip of
competition” or producer-consumer control of these
services leads to bureaucratic waste and inefficiency. This
is the material foundation for much working and middle class
support for “privatization” of government services in
the advanced capitalist countries.
[45]Power
and Money,
213.
[46]"In
Defense of Socialist Planning," New
Left Review 159 (September-October 1986), 5-38.
[47]Power
and Money,
202.
[48]Power
& Money,
197-214.
[49]"In
Defense of Socialist Planning," 9, 31-34.
[50]Power
and Money,
206. These arguments were first developed in Mandel's debate
with Alec Nove: Mandel, "In Defense of Socialist
Planning;" Nove, "Markets and Socialism" New
Left Review 161 (January-February 1987)98-104; Mandel,
"The Myth of Market Socialism," New
Left Review 169 (May-June 1988) 108-121.
Catherine
Samery, in Plan,
Market and Democracy,
Numbers 7-8 of the Notebooks for Study and Research (Amsterdam: International Institute
for Research and Education, 1988) and her contribution to
this volume, point out that Nove fails to distinguish
between the effects of different types of market mechanisms
in transitional, post-capitalist societies.
Nove tends to ignore the disastrous history of
“market reforms” in the bureaucratic regimes in the
east, which deepened social inequality without raising labor
productivity. Following
the suggestion of Diane Elson [“Market Socialism or
Socialization of the Market?” New Left Review 172 (November-December 1988), 3-44], Samurai
suggests that certain types of market regulation are
compatible with planning and workers’ democracy in the
transition to socialism.
[51]Power
and Money,
209-210, 240-246.
[52]Tony
Cliff, State
Capitalism in Russia (London: Pluto Press, 1975;
originally published in 1955); P. Binns, T. Cliff and C.
Harman, Russia:
From Workers' State to State Capitalism (London:
Bookmarks, 1987).
[53]Most
of these themes are contained in Mandel's debates with Chris
Harman and other members of the British "International
Socialist" current, The
Inconsistencies of State-Capitalism (London: IMG
Publications, 1969).
[54]Max
Shachtman, The
Bureaucratic Revolution: The Rise of the Stalinist State
(New York: The Donald Press, 1962); Jack Trautman, ed., Bureaucratic
Collectivism: The Stalinist Social System (Detroit, MI:
Sun Press, 1974).
[55]Jacek
Kuron and Karol Modzelewski, "Open Letter to Members of
the Warsaw Sections of the United Polish Workers Party and
the Union of Young Socialists," in G.L. Weissman (ed.),
Revolutionary Marxist Students In Poland Speak Out (1964-1968) (New
York: Merit Publishers, 1968), 15-90.
[56]Power
& Money,
28-30 (emphasis in the original).
[57]Power
and Money,
32 (emphasis in the original).
[58]Robert
Brenner, "The Origins of Capitalist Development: A
Critique of Neo-Smithian Marxism," New Left Review 104 (July-August 1977), 25-92.
[59]See
Catherine Samurai, Plan, Market and Democracy; R. Smith, "The Chinese Road to
Capitalism," New
Left Review 199 (May-June 1993), 55-99.
[60]Marxist
Economic Theory,
II, 572-574, 584-599; Beyond
Perestroika, Chapters 1 and 3..
[61]A.
Shaikh, The Current
Economic Crisis: Causes and Implications (Detroit, MI:
Against the Current Pamphlet, 1989); "The Falling Rate
of Profits and the Economic Crisis in the US" in R.
Cherry, et al.,
(eds), The Imperiled
Economy, Volume I: Macroeconomics
from a Left Perspective (New York: Union for Radical
Political Economics, 1987), 115-126; Mary C. Malloy,
"Finance and Industrial Capital in the Current Crisis:
On Brenner's 'Politics of U.S. Decline,'" Against the Current 57 (July-August 1995), 27-32.
[62]We
use, as did Marx, the terms "proletarian
dictatorship" and "workers' state"
interchangeably. See Hal Draper, Karl
Marx's Theory of Revolution, Volume III: The
"Dictatorship of the Proletariat" (New York:
Monthly Review Press, 1986).
[63]Marx,
The Civil War in
France in The
First International & After (New York: Random House,
1974);' V.I. Lenin, State
and Revolution in Selected
Works, II; The Proletarian Revolution and the Renegade Kautsky in Selected
Works, III.
[64]The
best statement of this position remains Trotsky, In
Defense of Marxism (New York: Pathfinder Press, 1970,
originally published 1940). See also Mandel, Revolutionary
Marxism Today, 141-150.
[65]Anderson,
"Trotsky's Interpretation of Stalinism," 123-124.
[66]Power
and Money,
74-75 (emphasis in the original).
[67]Revolutionary
Marxism Today,
142.
[68]For
a summary of the arguments about the new middle class, see
C. Post, "The New Middle Class?" Against the Current (Old Series) 2,4 (Winter 1984), 35-41.
[69]Revolutionary
Marxist Today,
143.
[70]Mandel
discusses the literature on the slowing rate of upward
mobility in the USSR in Beyond
Perestroika, Chapters
3 and 4.
|